Is the World Ready for a Guaranteed Basic Income? (Update)

36m
A lot of jobs in the modern economy don’t pay a living wage, and some of those jobs may be wiped out by new technologies. So what’s to be done? We revisit an episode from 2016 for a potential solution.

Listen and follow along

Transcript

Free Conomics Radio is sponsored by Whole Foods Market.

Fall Sports are back, and Whole Foods Market has everything you need to host a delicious game day party.

Set out a spread featuring heat-and-eat boneless chicken bites, shrimp cocktail platters, and 365 brand tortilla chips and salsa.

Feed your team made-in-house marinated chicken wings and Teton Waters Ranch hot dogs and sausages.

And don't forget 365 frozen apps, samosas, mac and cheese bites, sweet Potato Puffs, and more.

Host Game Day with help from Whole Foods Market.

At the University of Arizona, we believe that everyone is born with wonder.

That thing that says, I will not accept this world that is.

While it drives us to create what could be,

that world can't wait to see what you'll do.

Where will your wonder take you?

And what will it make you?

The University of Arizona.

wonder makes you

start your journey at wonder.arizona.edu

hey there it's stephen dubner over the past several years artificial intelligence has gone from something you read about to something you encounter once in a while to something that many of us use every day but a lot of people find it off-putting, even frightening.

One fear is that the more useful AI gets, the more it will displace human workers.

Companies like Amazon and Ford and JPMorgan are talking about reducing their workforce since the AIs can do some of the work at a fraction of the cost of human employees.

We have made several episodes that touch on this, including a 2023 series called How to Think About AI, guest hosted by Adam Davidson, and an episode from last October called What Do People Do All Day.

The fear that technology will replace human labor is nothing new.

In fact, it comes up in just about every generation.

There is also a proposed solution to this problem that comes up again and again.

A guaranteed basic income is what some people call it.

And we made an episode about that way back in 2016, years before anyone had heard of ChatGPT.

The idea was having a moment then, and now, thanks to the AI boom, it's having another moment.

So I wanted to replay that episode for you today.

We have gone through and updated facts and figures as necessary.

We'll begin with the economist Eric Brynjalfsson, who was at MIT when we spoke back then, but has since moved to Stanford.

Here's how Brynjalfsson describes the central problem.

We're now beginning to have machines be able to augment and automate our brains and replace mental tasks.

Machines can do computations and make decisions.

And we're still in the early stages of this, but we believe that the implications will be at least as profound as what the Industrial Revolution did for our muscles.

In a book he co-authored with Andrew McAfee, Brunjalfsson calls this technological disruption the second machine age.

Yes, it will likely produce gains in living standards, but it also might lead to a massive evaporation of jobs.

Emphasis on the might, this can be aggressively argued in either direction.

There are folks who are confident that the technology is going to lead to a bounty for all and make everyone better off.

And there are other people people who are very concerned that we'll have a jobless future and a lot of people will be left in poverty.

Take just one example.

Driverless cars, a technology I'm sure you've heard about.

The driverless car company Waymo now operates in five cities, and Uber hopes to roll out its driverless fleet next year.

So what happens to all the people who drive for a living?

Not just taxis and rideshare vehicles, but buses and trucks.

In the U.S.

alone, that is roughly 12 million people.

Sure, some new jobs will be created by driverless technology, but what are all those drivers supposed to do if their livelihood is obliterated?

There'll be winners and losers.

Already we're seeing that some kinds of tasks and skills are much less valuable, and people with those tasks and skills have seen their wages fall.

And so it hasn't been a rising tide that lifted all boats.

So if there's a massive evaporation of jobs, and if too many hardworking people continue to earn too little to live on, what happens next?

Could one solution to both problems be an idea that's been floating around in economic circles for decades?

Here's the idea.

What if everyone automatically received from the government a guaranteed basic income?

That's our question of the day on Freakonomics Radio.

Would it work?

Can governments afford it?

And what would happen if the financial incentive to work goes away?

Sure, maybe 90% of people will go smoke pot and play video games, but if 10% of the people go create incredible new products and services and new wealth, that's still a huge net win.

This is Freakonomics Radio, the podcast that explores the hidden side of everything with your host, Stephen Dubner.

A guaranteed or unconditional or universal basic income, a UBI, is an idea that economists have toyed with for years.

There are, of course, many forms of government welfare around the world, which are usually means tested, but universal payouts are rarer.

Since 1982, the Alaskan government has paid a dividend on oil revenues to all residents, about $1,700 a year on average.

After voters in Switzerland rejected a national guaranteed income plan in 2016, the city of Bern announced its own UBI experiment in 2024.

Similar trials have popped up in Spain, Finland, the Netherlands.

And how about in the U.S.?

The idea hasn't had much traction lately in Washington, although Bernie Sanders and Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez have both expressed support.

Maybe that's not too surprising since they are both on the socialist side of the political spectrum.

But here's the thing about a universal basic income.

You can see why a socialist or just about anyone on the left might like the idea, theoretically at least.

It is a permanent financial safety net.

But you'd think that conservatives would also like it, again, theoretically at least, because it is a way to shrink the welfare state by folding up a bunch of Byzantine entitlement programs into one tidy check.

Now, what would a guaranteed income program actually look like?

Where would the money come from?

And if you give everyone in America a check for maybe $20,000 every year, wouldn't inflation render the poor people just as poor as before?

These questions are all really, really hard to answer.

But we can probably learn at least a little bit by going back in time.

In the late 18th century, Founding father Thomas Paine argued for a substantial universal payout based on our collective share of the Earth's natural resources.

That didn't happen.

In the 1940s, the economists George Stigler and Milton Friedman helped put another version into play.

It was called a negative income tax.

It was meant to support people in grave need.

Here is the economist Evelyn Forgé.

So the idea was that if you had no income from any other source, you'd receive a certain level of income, a sort of socially agreed-upon level.

Forgé is an economist at the University of Manitoba.

And as your income from other sources, and in particular from the labor market, increased, your benefit would decline, but it would decline less than proportionately.

And here is Milton Friedman, in his usual direct style, explaining what he saw as the benefits of the idea.

The proposal for a negative income tax is a proposal to help poor people by giving them money, which is what they need, rather than as now, by requiring them to come before a governmental official, detail all their assets and their liabilities, and be told that you may spend X dollars on rent, Y dollars on food, et cetera, and then be given a handout.

The hope was that a negative income tax would streamline the burgeoning welfare system without diluting the incentive to work as much as the existing system did.

Our present welfare programs, our present direct relief, and aid-to-dependent children programs, in effect, have a 100% tax rate.

Because if a family on relief, if let's say a woman, as currently is mostly the case under aid-to-dependent children, if a woman who is on relief takes a job and earns $100, and she's honest, she is required to have her relief payment reduced by $100.

That's one of the ways in which we've been producing poor people.

More than a thousand economists from 125 American universities signed a statement supporting a national system of income guarantees and supplements.

The idea had support from many quarters, like the staunch libertarian Friedrich Hayek.

I have no objection against a flat minimum secure to everybody who cannot earn enough in the market to civil rights leader Martin Luther King.

all people and for all families of our country.

In 1968, the Republican president-elect Richard Nixon appointed as his urban affairs counselor Daniel Patrick Moynihan, the liberal sociologist and future Democratic senator who was intensely focused on race and poverty.

They created what came to be called the Family Assistance Plan.

What I am proposing is that the federal government build a foundation under the income of of every American family with dependent children that cannot care for itself.

And wherever in America, that family may live.

The family assistance plan was sent to Congress.

If it got through, it wouldn't be a guaranteed universal income, but rather a floor under incomes for poor families.

Nixon was very, very careful to draw this distinction.

This national floor under incomes for working or dependent families is not a guaranteed income.

Under the guaranteed income proposal, everyone would be assured a minimum income regardless of how much he was capable of earning, regardless of what his need was, regardless of whether or not he was willing to work.

A guaranteed income would undermine the incentive to work.

The family assistance plan that I propose increases the incentive to work.

But was this balance possible?

To find out, the federal government had begun a series of experiments.

The purpose of all of these experiments was to look at the labor market outcomes.

Evelyn Forgé again.

The big concern everybody had at the time was, you know, if you give people money for nothing, why won't they just quit their jobs?

Starting in 1968, the federal government ran a series of four negative tax experiments in different parts of the country with different demographics.

Low-income urban couples, rural families, black households, especially those headed by single women.

Selection was randomized, which meant there was always a control group.

This is thought to be the first time the U.S.

government used this kind of experimentation to measure the effects of a policy idea.

Granted, it would be many years before they'd have the data, and Nixon's family assistance plan was still making its way through the political channels.

Soon, a similar experiment was happening in Canada.

I was sitting in a first-year economics class at Glendon College in Toronto, and my professor came in and started to talk about this wonderful experiment that he said was being conducted way out west somewhere.

And it was going to revolutionize the way we delivered social programs.

Evelyn Forgé points out that the U.S.

movement had a conservative thrust, with Milton Friedman advocating for smaller government.

But Canada was different.

In Canada, the support tended to come from the left.

It was a sort of social democratic impulse, and most of the rhetoric was in terms of social justice.

It was called a mincome experiment, as in minimum income.

It was conducted in just a couple places, including a town of about 12,000 called Dauphin.

It's in Manitoba, a few hours northwest of Winnipeg.

Dauphin was a small town like a lot of other small towns in Canada.

It was very dependent on agriculture.

There was nothing unique about it, and that's what made it such an interesting saturation saturation site.

A saturation site, meaning that every person who met the income eligibility was offered the deal.

In Dauphin, that meant about 30% of the town.

If your income falls below a certain level, you'll receive so much.

And as your income increases, your benefit will be reduced.

The nice thing about the guaranteed annual income, because people get to keep a portion of their benefits as they go out to work, is that this becomes a supplement for the working poor as well.

And there's an encouragement to work.

So in the mid to late 1970s if you were unlucky enough to be poor but lucky enough to live in dauphin manitoba you would be eligible for a check from the government forgé says that a family of four would get the equivalent of roughly eighteen thousand current us dollars a year this was in lieu of any existing welfare benefits and it wasn't enough to give people a comfortable life.

When we interviewed a number of the participants, one of the participants had this lovely line that it it was enough to add some cream to the coffee.

That said, the Canadian government spent millions of dollars on the project, but for a good cause, right?

To find out if it could support its low-income citizens without killing the incentive to work.

So, did the MinCum experiment work well enough to be turned into policy?

What did the data show?

No one ever wrote a final report.

There was no more money forthcoming to do an evaluation of the project, and it's just disappeared.

Uh-oh.

Between an economic downturn and political upheaval, the Canadian Mincom Project lost its mojo.

The researchers were told to archive the data for future research, and effectively, what they did was to empty the file cabinets and put all the paper into cardboard boxes.

And how about back in the U.S.?

Did Nixon and Moynihan's plan do any better?

We'll find out after the break.

Free Conomics Radio is sponsored by Mint Mobile.

From new shoes to new supplies, the back-to-school season comes with a lot of expenses.

Your wireless bill shouldn't be one of them.

Ditch overpriced wireless and switch to Mint Mobile, where you can get the coverage and speed you're used to, but for way less money.

For a limited time, Mint Mobile is offering three months of unlimited premium wireless service for $15 a month because this school year, your budget deserves a break.

Get this new customer offer and your three-month unlimited wireless plan for just 15 bucks a month at mintmobile.com/slash freak.

That's mintmobile.com/slash freak.

Upfront payment of $45 required, equivalent to $15 per month.

Limited time, new customer offer for first three months only.

Speeds may slow above 35 gigabytes on unlimited plan.

Taxes and fees extra.

See Mint Mobile for details.

There used to be very little visibility and control in treasury.

Today, JP Morgan Payments delivers real-time dashboards and control at your fingertips.

That's the power of clarity.

That's JP Morgan Payments.

Copyright 2025, JP Morgan Chase Company, All Rights Reserve, JP Morgan Chase Bank, and a member of FDIC.

Deposits held in non-U.S.

branches are not FDIC insured.

Non-deposit products are not FDIC insured.

This is not a legal commitment for credit or services.

Availability varies.

Eligibility determined by JPMorgan Chase.

Visit jpmorgan.com/slash payments disclosure for details.

The fight

In our future and its potential.

Together, we answer America's call to win.

We are Marines.

We were made for this.

Before the break, we heard that Canada's guaranteed income experiment failed to materialize after years of planning and millions in spending.

Back in the States, things were not going much better.

The Nixon-Moynihan Family Assistance Plan had died in Congress.

The right thought it was too expensive.

The left thought it wasn't generous enough.

Ultimately, however, there were at least two direct legacies of the plan, which are still around today.

Supplemental security income, which increased federal support for the elderly, blind, and disabled, and the earned income tax credit, which is a small negative income tax, although not a guaranteed income.

By now, the political momentum for some kind of universal guaranteed income had greatly diminished, no matter what the data might have to say about whether such a thing could actually work.

But what did the data say?

The American experiments were still ongoing, and the final analysis was still way down the road.

In Canada, remember, the data had been packed up in cardboard boxes.

I finally did track it down.

That's Evelyn Forgé again.

I was doing a lot of work on the relationship between poverty and health outcomes, and I remembered this old experiment, and I wondered if I could find any link to health outcomes and to quality of life for the participants.

It took a while, but she found the boxes of data.

I found 1,800 of them in a warehouse in Winnipeg under the authority of the National Archives.

But, I mean, I was literally looking at 1,800 boxes full of really badly organized data.

No one had ever constructed a database, and no analysis had been done.

She thought about going through the boxes and building a database.

And I sort of realized that my life was finite and I wasn't going to be able to do anything with that particular data.

But thinking about the MinCome experiment in Dauphin did give Forger an idea.

One of the defining features of this period in Canada was that this was the period when universal health insurance was introduced.

And one of the unanticipated consequences of universal health insurance is that you collect quite a lot of data on individuals.

And those data had been sorted and digitized, data on education, employment, and of course health.

So what if Forger could look in these data for people who lived in Dauphin and who presumably got that extra government money and then compared them to other low-income people in other towns who didn't get that mincome boost?

And I was able to find everybody who was living in Dauphin during that particular period.

So the first thing I did was to look at hospitalization rates, and I found that hospitalization rates had fallen by about 8.5%

for the test group and Dauphin relative to the match control group.

Okay, so it looked like the MinCum recipients were healthier.

What else did Forger find in the data?

One of the findings was that high school completion rates had increased.

And we discovered fairly quickly that boys in particular in low-income families had been under a fair amount of pressure to become self-supporting as quickly as they could.

When MinCome came along, some of the families decided that they could allow their sons to stay in high school just a little bit longer.

So instead of quitting school at age 16 and getting their first full-time job, these boys stayed in school until they were 18, until they graduated from high school, and took their first full-time job a little bit later.

So in the raw data, it might look like employment fell since a bunch of 16 and 17-year-old boys were not joining the workforce.

But in fact, this was good news since they were staying in school, presumably setting themselves up for a better work life.

But what about employment among grown-ups?

That's the big concern of any guaranteed income plan.

Did they stop working once they started getting a government check?

Grown-up people with full-time jobs don't actually reduce the number of hours they work by very much.

One exception, women, especially those who wanted more time off after having a baby.

At the time, I think the legal entitlement was four weeks.

And it's sort of interesting because, as a society, we've already decided that longer parental leaves are something that we want to support.

So they effectively anticipated that policy change.

So the effects of the Canadian MinCome experiment seem to be pretty positive.

Now, keep in mind, the dollars to do this have to come from somewhere, new taxes or cuts in entitlements or other services.

That, of course, is going to be a major part of any discussion about any guaranteed income plan.

But the data seemed to show that the biggest concern that everyone would just quit their jobs did not happen, at least in the Canadian experiment.

Now, what about the U.S.

experiments?

In general, the finding was that primary earners really don't reduce the number of hours they work very much when you offer a guaranteed annual income.

It's secondary earners and tertiary earners, that is, second adult incomes and the incomes of adolescents that fall a little bit.

Very similar to the Canadian results.

So there too, the news was pretty good, although there was something troubling in the U.S.

data.

When the findings started to come in, it looked like the families that were receiving a guaranteed annual income might in fact have a higher divorce rate.

And this became very political very quickly in the U.S.

There were all kinds of concerns that this was an attack on the American family.

Daniel Patrick Moynihan, a champion of the guaranteed income idea, was also a champion of the nuclear family.

The divorce findings led him to withdraw his support.

But Evelyn Forgé says that when the data were examined more carefully over time, the divorce controversy seems to have been overblown.

There was a subsequent work about a decade later which suggested that it might have been a statistical anomaly.

So the evidence from these experiments, as narrow as it may be, seems to suggest that a guaranteed income can produce positive results.

The funding and the politics are, of course, separate and large questions, but one reason the idea has gained momentum lately is that the world has changed a lot since those experiments.

Our economies have changed a lot.

There's already been wage stagnation.

Technological disruption keeps on coming.

All of which makes at least one economist, Evelyn Forgé, think that the timing is right.

I do see a fundamental and ongoing change in the way the labor market operates, and I do think that we need to make some fundamental changes in the way we deliver social programs.

I think a guaranteed annual income could do a very nice job of addressing some of these issues.

But coming up on Freak Economics Radio, politics being what they are, who is best positioned to figure out how to actually create a successful and affordable guaranteed income program?

And if you are worried that a world full of people not hard at work, at traditional work at least, would lead to chaos, just remember that some people not hard at work have been pretty useful to society.

I think if you look at the 18th and at the 19th century, some of the great scientific breakthroughs and some of the great cultural breakthroughs were made by people who did not work.

Trade for the best Hondas, the most awarded brand in Car and Driver 10 best history.

Save thousands on a new Honda today with 0% financing.

Get more for your trade and save on the best gas, hybrid, and EV vehicles with financing as low as zero APR on a new Honda like the 2025 Prologue.

Visit your local Honda dealer today.

See dealer for financing details.

Financing on credit approval offer N93025.

JP Morgan Payments helps you drive efficiency with automated payments and intelligent algorithms across 200 countries and territories.

That's automation-driven finance.

That's JPMorgan Payments.

JP Morgan Internal Data 2024, Copyright 2025, JPMorgan Chase ⁇ Company, All Rights Reserve, JP Morgan Chase Bank, and a member FDIC.

Deposits held in non-U.S.

branches are not FDIC insured.

Non-deposit products are not FDIC insured.

This is not a legal commitment for credit or services.

Availability varies.

Eligibility determined by J.P.

Morgan Chase.

Visit jpmorgan.com/slash payments.

Disclosure for details.

For a limited time at McDonald's, get a Big Mac extra-value meal for $8.

That means two all-beef patties, special sauce, lettuce, cheese, pickles, onions on a sesame seed bun, and medium fries, and a drink.

We may need to change that jingle.

Prices and participation may vary.

I'm Stephen Dubner.

This is Free Conomics Radio.

For many people, wages have stagnated.

For many others, their jobs may be disappearing entirely.

What's to be done so that financially vulnerable people aren't just crushed?

One of the most radical proposals is for a guaranteed basic income.

While several governments are starting to experiment with this idea, economists are not universal in their support.

Here's Robert Gordon, author of The Rise and Fall of American Growth.

As far as the guaranteed minimum income, I'm not in favor of that.

I'm in favor of a modest increase in the minimum wage and a substantial increase in the earned income tax credit, which encourages low-income people to work.

Why would you not be in favor of the minimum guaranteed income?

There's too much of an incentive if you guarantee income to replace work.

And if you provide a guaranteed minimum income to everybody, then those with low skills will drop out of the labor force and will no longer work.

So I think it's a matter of incentives.

A guaranteed minimum income would put a very high implicit marginal tax rate on going to work for those with relatively low skills.

Is Robert Gordon right?

Are boosting the minimum wage and the earned income tax credit better solutions than a universal basic income?

Or what about wage insurance where the government supplements the income of people whose jobs just don't pay enough to live on?

Again, these questions are nearly impossible to answer right now, but let's assume the guaranteed basic income idea is worth pursuing.

How would it work?

Would it require a huge tax hike, or would the money come from efficiency or productivity gains, or from eliminating other government benefits?

There are the metaphysical questions as well.

Does basic income make people happy and fulfilled?

Does it make them less stressed?

Does it make them do better long-term planning?

That is Sam Altman, the co-founder and CEO of Open AI, the startup that kicked off the current AI revolution with ChatGPT.

When we spoke with him for this episode, though, back in 2016, he was the president of Y Combinator.

And what is Y Combinator?

Y Combinator is a company that funds startups.

Meaning a venture capital firm.

For instance,

we've invested in Airbnb, Dropbox, Stripe, Zeniths, Instacart, Reddit.

We've invested in about 1,100 companies in total.

But also...

More recently, we also have started funding basic research.

Which is not what VC firms typically do.

No, but I think we're a fairly unusual venture capital firm.

For instance, when we spoke with him, Altman was launching an in-house research project on a guaranteed basic income.

The tentative plan is to hire a social science researcher and to have him or her pick a group of people and give some of them them some amount of money, maybe different amounts of money for five years and observe what happens relative to a control group.

What happens would include all kinds of metrics.

Do their personal balance sheets go up?

Do they learn new skills?

Do they create new wealth for society?

All of those sorts of things.

The research would also try to figure ways to drive down the baseline cost of living.

The biggest problem, Altman says, is housing.

And that is the hardest thing to fix with technology.

It's the most dependent on policy other than housing.

I think we we can make great progress just with technology.

But if you think about a world where we get nuclear fusion to work, we make continued progress on agricultural technology and water technology and transportation, or we use technology to really make education a lot more efficient, you can easily see the costs of the baseline come down a huge amount.

And I think if you're not a kind of a crazy techno optimist, which I'd say I am, you underweight that.

Being a techno optimist in Silicon Valley is why Altman started thinking about a basic income.

I think there is a sense that technological job destruction is accelerating more than people outside of Silicon Valley realize.

And I think this is mostly narrow applications of AI,

but it's going to happen for lots of other reasons.

So every time we've had a major societal revolution of some sort, you know, we had the agricultural revolution, we have the industrial revolution, where anytime you have a significant fraction of human jobs get eliminated in a relatively short period of time, eventually humans do figure out new things to do, but there's quite a lot of disruption while they're happening.

And so I think people in Silicon Valley are saying, man, there are going to be incredible changes in the next few decades.

What can we do to make that as smooth as possible?

I do think that as we as a society get richer and richer, there should be some sort of floor for everybody.

And in a way, basic income is sort of the libertarian approach to doing this, right?

It's actually healthy for a society if some people get incredibly rich.

But there should be a floor below which we as a society don't allow people to fall.

You could argue that why Combinator's funding of basic income research is a guilt play, since it is the kind of company that helps create so much of the technological disruption that may destroy jobs.

Altman would disagree with that argument.

So we view our job as to increase the amount of innovation in the world.

And mostly that means funding startups.

But that is the mission, not funding startups in itself.

In Altman's view, the idea of a basic income isn't counterintuitive at all, even in a capitalist framework.

He sees it as perfectly intuitive.

I think the default belief of a child is that everyone should get food to eat and a place to sleep.

And it strikes most children as incredibly unfair that that's not the case.

In fact, I think that's so universal that is somehow probably encoded into our genes, this idea of fairness and equality.

And I think people then get older and move away from it.

Every conversation you have with anyone about the idea of a basic income inevitably comes around to one point, the value of work.

Not just the financial payoff, but what you might call the moral payoff.

That if anyone who wanted to could get a basic income without working, that it might destroy our moral fiber, our social fiber.

Here again is the Stanford economist Eric Brinjalfsson.

People get a lot of meaning from participating and contributing to society.

And the way we're set up right now, if we just got rid of the jobs and replaced it with a check, I think a lot of people would be unhappy.

Sam Altman isn't so sure.

Maybe 90% of people will go smoke pot and play video games.

But if 10% of the people go create incredible new products and services and new wealth, that's still a huge net win.

And the kind of American puritanical ideal that hard work for its own sake is valuable, period.

And you can't question that.

I think that's just wrong.

Y Combinator's guaranteed income experiment finally got off the ground in 2020 with 3,000 people in Illinois and Texas getting $1,000 a month for three years.

Their average income was less than $29,000 a year.

So this was a big boost for them.

They typically used the extra money to pay for essentials like rent, food, and transportation.

And they worked a bit less, about an hour and 20 minutes less each week on average.

How should we interpret that?

Here again is the economist Evelyn Forgé.

I think people do need to create meaning in their lives, and for a lot of people, that does come through work.

I'm not sure that they necessarily need eight hours of work a day and 40 hours of work a week to find that meaning.

Forger, like Sam Altman, sees a potentially huge upside in freeing people of the need to work.

If you look at the 18th and at the 19th century, some of the great scientific breakthroughs and some of the great cultural breakthroughs were made by people who did not work.

These were gentlemen of leisure, right?

These were people who had enough family money to support themselves.

They certainly didn't have to dirty their hands doing the kinds of work we take for granted.

I don't think these individuals felt useless.

I don't think their contribution was negligible.

I think it was very important to the development of the world.

That may all be true, but if, for whatever reasons, we all start working a lot less, whether or not there's a guaranteed income involved, humankind is in for a big change.

For most of civilization, work has been a huge part of what it means to be human.

So what happens if the techno-optimist dream comes true?

What happens if computers and robots can take care of most or all of our work?

Will our robot overlords even want us around anymore?

Or will we just be in their way?

Sure, it's a troubling thought, but consider one example, which may seem way off base at first, but consider another population that used to have to work for a living.

The relationship between dogs and humans goes way back.

We know that dogs were not just the first domesticated animal, the first domesticated anything.

That's Gregor Larson.

I'm at the University of Oxford in the Department of Archaeology, and for the purposes of this, I'm studying the origins and evolution of dogs.

The domestication process was long and complicated.

So what we think may have happened is that a pack of wolves, rather than following, say, caribou or going after megafauna or something else, started following us instead because the wolves could make a living simply by living off of the back end of us.

And in doing so, they would put a selection pressure on themselves to become more acclimated to us.

More acclimated and, over time, more useful.

Let's say you are hunting and you just nick your prey.

If you have a dog with you and whatever you've just nicked is leaving a blood trail, that dog will be able to sniff out that injured animal and then locate it.

And so all you have to do is follow it.

Over time, dogs did all kinds of work for us.

They herded cattle.

They guarded our property.

They even helped cook our food.

Seriously, a breed called the Turn Spit Dog had a long body, short legs, and it would run in a wheel that turned a a spit over a fire to make sure the meat cooked evenly.

These dogs were bred, or at least the best ones were just able to sit in these wheels, and that's all they did all day, is just run and run and run and run.

Eventually, technology put the turn spit dog out of a job, just as technology may eventually put a lot of people out of jobs.

A lot of dog work was replaced with machinery or other technology.

Like people, some of them found new and different work as guide dogs, as therapy dogs.

Dogs were trained to sniff out drugs or explosives, even illness in a human.

Here at Freakonomics Radio, we've given one particularly clever pack of dogs some very specific training.

But let's face it, most dogs aren't that clever.

So when their jobs began to disappear, they did not find new work.

So did dogs just vanish?

No, they did not.

In fact, they flourished.

When we no longer needed them as workmates, we turned them into pets.

In the U.S.

alone, about 65 million households own a dog.

They are far and away the most common pet.

Cats are second in about 46 million households.

Freshwater fish are a distant distant third in 11 million households.

Between 2018 and 2022, our spending on pets went up by 51% to $136 billion.

So if you look at the long term, dogs went from being on the production side of the human equation to the consumption side, big time.

So who's to say that we, their masters, won't find a way to make peace with our robotic masters even when we no longer have any work to do.

Personally, I think I would make a great pet for anyone willing to adopt me.

Anyone interested?

Serious inquiries only, please, to radio at freakonomics.com.

That's it for this updated episode.

We will be back very soon with a new one.

Until then, take care of yourself.

And if you can, someone else too.

Freakonomics Radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud Radio.

This episode was produced by Greg Rosalski and updated by Dalvin Abuaji.

It was mixed by Eleanor Osborne.

The Freakonomics Radio Network staff also includes Alina Coleman, Augusta Chapman, Ellen Frankman, Elsa Hernandez, Gabriel Roth, Greg Ripon, Jasmine Klinger, Jeremy Johnston, Morgan Levy, Sarah Lilly, Teo Jacobs, and Zach Lipinski.

You can find our entire archive on any podcast app or at freakonomics.com where we publish transcripts and show notes.

Our theme song is Mr.

Fortune by the Hitchhikers.

Our composer is Louise Guerra.

As always, thank you for listening.

Can you describe an invention or maybe a series of inventions that

you could foresee radically changing the future?

Can you imagine what those?

Do you have a wish list?

How can I imagine something that you just said I can't imagine?

The Freakonomics Radio Network, the hidden side of everything.

Stitcher.

Trade for the best, Hondas, the most awarded brand in Car and Driver 10 best history.

Save thousands on a new Honda today with 0% financing.

Get more for your trade and save on the best gas, hybrid, and EV vehicles with financing as low as zero APR on a new Honda like the 2025 Prologue.

Visit your local Honda dealer today.

See dealer for financing details.

Financing on credit approval offer N93025.

JP Morgan Payments helps you drive efficiency with automated payments and intelligent algorithms across 200 countries and territories.

That's automation-driven finance.

That's JP Morgan Payments.

JP Morgan Internal Data 2024, Copyright 2025, JP Morgan Chase Company, All Rights Reserve, JP Morgan Chase Bank, and a member FDIC.

Deposits held in non-U.S.

branches are are not FDIC insured.

Non-deposit products are not FDIC insured.

This is not a legal commitment for credit or services.

Availability varies.

Eligibility determined by J.P.

Morgan Chase.

Visit JPMorgan.com/slash payments.

Disclosure for details.

Your sausage mcmuffin with egg didn't change.

Your receipt did.

The sausage mcmuffin with egg extra value meal includes a hash brown and a small coffee for just $5.

Only at McDonald's for a limited time.

Prices and participation may vary.