Trump’s Tariff Disaster

56m
On this episode of The David Frum Show, The Atlantic’s David Frum examines how protectionism, once a fringe idea in U.S. politics, became central to modern Republican trade policy. He traces how President Donald Trump made tariffs a political weapon, and why these policies continue to carry political appeal despite their economic cost.

Then David is joined by the historian and trade expert Doug Irwin for a conversation about what tariffs actually do. Irwin explains how protectionist policies have repeatedly backfired in American history, why they persist, and how the U.S. abandoned the bipartisan free-trade consensus that lasted for nearly a century. The two discuss who really pays for tariffs, why tariffs rarely achieve their stated goals, and what it would take to rebuild political support for open markets.

Get more from your favorite Atlantic voices when you subscribe. You’ll enjoy unlimited access to Pulitzer-winning journalism, from clear-eyed analysis and insight on breaking news to fascinating explorations of our world. Subscribe today at TheAtlantic.com/listener.
Learn more about your ad choices. Visit megaphone.fm/adchoices

Listen and follow along

Transcript

Introducing the U Rules of Value from Burger King.

And you rule number one, you choose food you actually want.

There's seven tasty options.

So try the $5 duo or $7 trio.

Choose your deal.

Price and participation varied.

Less only, no substitutions, restrictions apply.

What if an appliance emergency didn't have to be?

If your appliances suddenly decided they were done, don't stress.

Best Buy has you covered with a wide variety of major appliances from trusted brands in stock and available now.

So you don't have to worry about laundry piling up, refilling the fridge, or that big dinner party you're hosting.

Because Best Buy has the knowledge and expertise to get you the right appliance for your home.

Learn more at bestbuy.com.

Best Buy.

Imagine that.

Hello, and welcome back to the David Frum Show.

I'm David Frum, a staff writer at The Atlantic.

My guest today will be Douglas Irwin, who teaches at Dartmouth College and is, in my opinion, America's leading expert on the history of trade and tariffs in this country.

We'll be talking directly about many of the myths that are offered by protectionists to justify trade restrictions, tariffs.

We'll be looking at episodes from American economic history and refuting some of the stories that the protectionists tell to justify their otherwise obviously self-harming policies.

Before we begin, though, a few thoughts about some very recent events.

I am recording this podcast a few hours after the Trump administration announced a supposedly big deal with the European Union that will see Americans paying much higher tariffs on everything they import from the countries of Europe.

We are speaking a few hours before, or a few days before, the August 1st deadline for a whole lot more tariffs on everything from all the rest of the world.

Now, these measures follow announced so-called trade deals with Japan, about which the details are extremely hazy and where the details keep changing and where the Japanese don't seem at all to have the same idea of what has been agreed, if anything, that the United States does.

And shortly after, announcements of equally vaporous agreements with Britain and with China.

There's a kind of trade truce in effect with China where the round of trade tariff increases has stopped, rising and rising and rising, but Americans are still paying more for everything because of the Trump tariffs than they were.

That's a tax paid by the Americans least able to pay taxes.

It's a tax that exempts all of the wealthiest people who spend more of their money on things that aren't internationally traded, services here at home.

Remember, the dues at the country club aren't subject to the tariff.

Your rent and your fancy penthouse, that's not subject to a tariff.

But the knives and forks on the dinner tables of ordinary people, those are tariffed.

So we are seeing also a slowdown in the American economy.

Beginning about April, when the Trump tariffs were announced, the growth projections for the United States economy have been slowing.

We're not in a recession yet, but this year is obviously shaping up up to be much less prosperous than people expected at the beginning of the year.

I want to talk a little bit about what the Trump tariffs do and what the Trump tariffs do not do.

Let me start with what they do not do.

Tariffs are advertised as a way to increase your country's manufacturing.

What you do is you put a tax on all manufacturers from other countries.

That makes those other manufacturers more expensive.

And therefore, your manufacturers are more competitive.

Not only that, better still, your manufacturers can increase their prices because they're shielded from competition.

That makes them more profitable so they can afford to hire more people and put out more goods.

That's the theory, that by shielding your domestic industry from competition, you will be able to produce more and therefore export more.

And you will fix this trade balance that the Trump people are so upset about.

The trade balance being the difference between what you import and what you export.

None of this is true.

And any economist of any merit will agree.

Here's what tariffs actually do.

First, they hurt your manufacturing.

Remember, every manufactured good has inputs in it.

Every product is an input into the next product.

What tariffs do is they raise the price of all your inputs.

So the Trump people say, we have to bring back American shipbuilding.

Oh, yeah, we've increased the price of steel.

We have to bring back American automobiles.

Oh, yeah, we've increased the price of aluminum, of glass, and electronic components.

Everything that they are promising America will make more of is going to be made of things that are more expensive and often a lot more expensive.

Some of these tariffs are in the vicinity of 50%.

And so what you'll find is even if the tariff is sufficient to protect the American product, it can't be sold to the rest of the world.

The American ship made out of a high-cost American steel will not be able to compete on world markets with the South Korean ship or the Chinese ship.

America's manufacturing exports will go down, not up.

And by losing export markets, America will see its manufacturing actually tend to shrivel rather than to grow.

The Trump people say it'll fix the trade balance.

That is, we'll import less and export more.

Well, that's not true either.

We won't export more even of

non-industrial goods because other countries will retaliate.

You know, before Donald Trump became president the first time, the United States was the world's largest exporter of soybeans.

Trump imposed tariffs on China.

They retaliated by switching their soybean purchases from the United States to Brazil and Argentina.

And America's share of the world's soybean market collapsed.

And America is now far behind Brazil as a soybean producer and exporter.

During the 24 Trump election campaign, the Trump people had the nerve to say, under Biden, the United States became a net importer of food.

Yeah, that's true.

You know why?

Because the Trump tariffs wrecked the export market for American soybeans and other agricultural products.

So the United States imported pretty much the same as it always had, but exported less and so became more of a net importer.

And that effect on imports is what you see everywhere that tariffs are imposed.

What tariffs are doing is severing America from all of its tating relations, making other countries less willing to buy American goods and separating the United States from the rest of the world.

You know, they advertise the tariffs as a way to check China.

But the way you check China is by having friends and allies.

And America under Trump has a lot fewer of those.

The Trump people have come back from their talks in Europe by saying, look, we've built this giant trading bloc of the United States plus the EU.

Look how powerful we are.

But the European Union now regards the United States, and every European does.

And I'm speaking to you from Canada where this is true, once America's most intimate economic partner.

People see the United States as a dangerous predator on world markets, one that you want to have less and less to do with in the years ahead, because Americans can't be trusted.

The deals that the United States signed become worthless, like the trade deals with Canada and Mexico that Donald Trump signed in his first term, and he disregarded in the second.

No one wants to do business with you, with a person who approaches business in a mood of relentless bad faith.

No, it won't reverse the trade deficit.

It won't boost manufacturing.

It won't boost U.S.

exports.

It won't check American imports.

And it won't balance China.

All of those things will not happen.

So here's what will happen.

First, we're going to see slower economic growth.

And that shows up in every economic model because everything that Americans make that depends on inputs from the rest of the world, all of those things become less, become, those inputs become more expensive and the goods become less competitive.

And so you're going to see a slowdown in growth.

You're going to see a slowdown in business investment because the rules change all the time.

Americans don't know what to build, who to sell it to.

They don't know if they'll have customers overseas for anything.

And they don't know whether foreigners will buy American goods because the foreigners will be retaliating.

You'll see a slowdown in business investment and a slowdown in growth.

You're going to see the government having a much bigger role in economic life, picking winners and picking losers.

One of the reasons that the United States moved away from tariffs as a way of funding the government back in the early 20th century was because it led to so much corruption as different interests bought their way into protection and favors from the United States government.

It creates privileged winners.

And here's one more thing it does.

And this this is maybe the most important of all.

Once you see a tariff as a tax on those Americans least able to pay, it's pretty hard to think of it as anything else.

When the Trump people boast that they're on their way to trillions of dollars of new revenue, understand that what they're talking about is financing the tax cut for the rich that they passed just weeks ago in

this one giant, big, boastful bill.

And they're going to offset a lot of those revenue losses that were given to the richest people in America by having a massive tax on the consumption of the poorest people in America.

A tariff is a tax on the poorest people because it falls most heavily on goods.

Tariffs shift the burden of taxation onto the goods.

They tend to fall most heavily on the least expensive goods, and they impose the greatest costs on those Americans who spend more of their incomes on goods, less on services, less on saving, those least able to pay.

What we are seeing here is a massive redistribution of the fiscal burden of the United States, the tax burden of the United States, from those best able to pay, from those least able to pay.

And the whole thing is being being mystified and disguised by appealing to people's envy and spite and ignorance and mistrust of foreigners.

Trump is fooling you, trying to make you angry at the outside world for things that are happening because he is choosing to do them to make taxes fall more heavily on the average person, less heavily on those best able to pay, destroying the world trading system, severing the United States from allies.

And all of this is advertised as a win.

They advertise them as wins because they say, look, The United States is imposing all these tariffs on Americans.

And the other countries, the Japanese, the Europeans, they're not doing the same to their own people.

See, we win.

Our tariff on them is higher than their tariff on us.

But all that that means is that the Trump administration is more willing to inflict pain on Americans than European and Japanese governments are willing to inflict pain on their people.

Their governments are trying to protect their people from the consequences of American tariffs.

The United States government is eagerly accepting the consequences of American tariffs for Americans.

And why not?

Because once you understand that the whole purpose here of the Trump administration is to move the burden of taxes from themselves and their friends to those least able to pay, and to mobilize ignorance and hatred of foreigners and prejudice and team spirit as ways to disguise the pocket picking that is really going on, then you see why they may call this a win.

They win, you lose.

And the you here is not just the ordinary person who needs to buy tomatoes or automobiles or any good that includes any foreign component, which is every good.

The losers here are the American economy as a whole, which will grow more slowly.

The losers here are Americans looking for security in the world because they will have fewer friends and allies.

The losers here include future generation of Americans.

We're discovering that as crushingly as Trump raises tariffs on those least able to pay, it's still not enough to compensate for all his big tax cuts everywhere.

So the deficits and the debt that future generations of Americans must grow.

A question occurs.

Given the harmfulness of tariffs to growth, to the whole economy, why are indicators of the economy doing pretty well?

The stock market collapsed or sank on the first shock of Trump's tariffs back in April, but now there are more and more tariffs, and yet the stock market seems to be revived and holding its own, at least the U.S.

stock market.

Now, the U.S.

dollar has dropped against other currencies, so if you're measuring your stock market portfolio in Euros or yen, you're not as well off as you are if you just measure it in dollars.

But still, the shock in dollars is not as big as you might expect.

Why not a bigger shock?

I think one answer to that is that many investors are expecting the courts to strike down the Trump tariff program.

In May of 2025, the United States Court of International Trade ruled that Trump had exceeded his authority by imposing all of these many different tariffs on his presidential say-so.

And I think a lot of investors are betting that other courts and ultimately the United States Supreme Court will agree with the U.S.

Court of International Trade that the tariffs exceed Trump's authority.

But if those bets are wrong, if the courts do, as they so often have done, appease Trump, accommodate Trump, go along with Trump, we're going to be seeing a big shock and soon and hard.

Trump is plundering the country, counting on hatred of foreigners and mistrust of foreigners as the emotional disguise that will allow him to plunder the country, and leaving everyone with a terrible bill in lower growth, fewer friends to be paid by this generation of Americans and the next.

It's a scandal, it's a disgrace, but it's the future.

And now, my discussion with Douglas Irwin.

But first, a quick break.

Packages by Expedia.

You were made to occasionally take the hard route to the top of the Eiffel Tower.

We were made to easily bundle your trip.

Expedia.

Made to travel.

Flight-inclusive packages are at all protected.

Recently, we asked some people about sharing their New York Times accounts.

I would be very interested in having separate logins for a shared subscription.

I'm 35 years old.

I still share my parents' New York Times subscription.

I think if my my teenagers were to have their own logins, we could share articles.

It doesn't let us play the same games as each other.

I do the crossword.

I do the spelling B.

I do the wordle.

Please help.

Having our own accounts would be amazing.

My mom could save her own recipes.

My friends could save their recipes.

I want to get the weekly newsletter, but they seem to always go to my husband and then he doesn't forward them to me.

We both love cooking.

I'm a 30-minute and under-dinner girly.

My boyfriend is very elaborate.

I think him having his own profile would be great.

We love the New York Times and we would love to love it individually.

We heard you.

Introducing the New York Times family subscription.

One subscription, up to four separate logins for anyone in your life.

Find out more at nytimes.com slash family.

Douglas Irwin is America's leading historian of tariffs and trade.

A professor at Dartmouth, he is the author of seven books on trade history, including the 2018 masterwork, Clashing Over Commerce.

Clashing Over Commerce won the Manhattan Institute's Hayek Award for the best book on economics and personal liberty.

I devoted most of the summer of 2023 to Clashing Over Commerce and are repaid every minute.

It's a history of the whole flow of trade and tariffs in the United States from the founding era to the present.

It's a sad statement that we need the highest wisdom of the finest minds to refute the ignorance of fools and the deceits of the malicious.

But there it is, and here we are.

Doug Irwin, welcome to the David Frum Show.

Thank you very much for having me.

It's a pleasure to be here.

All right, I'm going to begin with some basics, and then I want to cover some historical issues that I think will be of value to people who feel a lot of the stream of events takes too much for granted.

I think for many of us of a certain age, tariffs like banking were chapters of the history books we skipped over to get from the Civil War to the First World War.

And that was all ancient history, but now it's the future.

So take this from the beginning.

What is a tariff?

What does it do?

Who pays it?

Well, a tariff is a tax on imported goods.

And it's something that the Constitution gives Congress the power to levy.

In fact, there's one reason why we have the Constitution in some sense is because of the difficulty we had with trade policy in the 1790s under the Articles of Confederation, 1780s, that is.

So it's a tax on imports.

It's designed for one of three purposes I sort of emphasize in clashing over commerce: Revenue.

So it's a tax, so it raises revenue.

Restriction.

You might want to use the tariff to keep out foreign goods.

Notice there's a conflict between those two.

If you want the revenue, you want the imports to keep coming in.

You just levy the tax on those imports.

If you want to keep the imports out, you raise the tax high enough.

There's not going to be much revenue, but you give space to domestic producers by keeping out those imports.

And then the last one is reciprocity, which is sort of a bargaining chip.

So throughout history, the United States has used tariffs to achieve all three of those objectives in various different ways, but that's essentially what it is.

You mentioned that the Constitution awards power over tariffs and trade to Congress.

How is it that the President is announcing new whimsical tariffs, announcing them every week, removing them every week, adjusting them every week, giving deadlines?

How is the President doing something that Congress is supposed to do according to the Constitution?

How did that happen?

Well, we'll get into this when we get into the flow of the ebbs and flows of trade policy history.

But in the 1930s, we shifted from a sort of Congress-dominated system of the tariffs to the president.

Congress started delegating powers over the tariff to the president.

And that delegation has gone on since the 1930s.

It's gotten bigger and broader over time, largely, I think, because Congress sort of trusted the president to act in the national interest and was a force for opening markets and liberalizing trade.

But now, over time, the president has a lot of power over trade, and this president uses it very differently than previous presidents.

So, Congress sort of said, look, we know we have a drinking problem.

Here's the keys to the liquor cabinet.

You're a responsible, sober adult.

We know you will not foolishly and promiscuously swig the Curacao.

So over to you.

And then it turns out they handed it over to a man who's only swigging the curacao, but mixing it with green alcohol to make an extra potent punch.

You said it much better than I could, yes.

And then we're all splashing around.

I want to go ask you some historical questions because there are people who are shameless enough or ignorant enough to defend what President Trump is doing in the trade realm.

So let's try to meet ignorance and malice with some knowledge.

Let me start with a couple of basic arguments that you often hear.

You hear them from the president.

You hear them from the people who influence the president.

As you point out in your book, the period from the Civil War to the Great Depression is a period of mostly high tariffs.

There's a little interruption along the way, but mostly very high tariffs from the Civil War to the Great Depression.

And during that period, America rose to industrial greatness.

So people will argue, well, look, these two things happened at the same time.

We had a lot of tariffs and we rose to industrial greatness.

It must be that the tariffs caused the rise to industrial greatness.

You hear that a lot.

What's wrong with it?

Well, it's a classic case of correlation not being causation.

So yes, the two went hand in hand, but there are a lot of other things going on between the Civil War and the Great Depression.

We had massive immigration.

We had massive capital accumulation, and we'll get into some of the causes of those.

But also this idea that the tariffs were causing that industrial growth.

We also have the period before the Civil War.

That's a period in which 20 or 30 years before the Civil War, tariffs were going down.

But the U.S.

industrialized at exactly the same rate then as we did after the Civil War.

So it's not like the post-Civil War period was this tremendous industrial boom.

It was, but we were also booming before the Civil War when the tariffs were low.

U.S.

manufacturing was growing quite rapidly before the Civil War with those lower tariffs as well.

So right there, there's sort of a bit of a problem with that idea that the tariffs were causing the growth.

But so many things are happening after the Civil War.

I mean, one of the things that economic historians point to is that we had important banking legislation that really increased the return to saving.

And so we had a massive savings and investment boom.

And of course, that was going somewhere.

It was going into building railroads, in terms of building manufacturing industries.

We had tremendous Western expansion.

A lot of the employment in manufacturing was through by immigrants coming from Italy and elsewhere in Europe, not by native-born Americans.

So, between the capital accumulation, the massive immigration, the openness to capital flows, and the transfer of technology from the UK, sorting out and trying to parse out exactly the contribution of the tariff to all that is very

difficult.

And what people have found, including some recent work by some other economic historians, is that US productivity growth was not particularly strong after the Civil War.

We saw a lot of expansion in the service sector, transportation improvements with the railroads and what have you, but it's not as though manufacturing was some sort of great productivity buster or experienced some big sort of boom.

Once again, the tariffs may have inhibited things as much as helped them because a lot of our imports were intermediate goods.

Yeah.

Well, I want, if I can supplement that with three points that the Brad Lighthizers and President Trump, when he's trying to repeat what Brad Lighthizer says, miss.

Yeah, actually, I think it's Robert Lighthiser.

Robert Lighthiser.

Thank you.

I beg your pardon.

Three things they miss.

The first is that the world in the era after the Civil War is becoming generally more protectionist.

And so the United States was the largest area of free trade that was available anywhere on the planet.

It was a bigger free trade zone than Germany.

I mean, Germany had high tariffs, France had high tariffs, Britain remained a free trade country in the 19th century.

But you could trade freely inside the United States over one of the largest trade spaces that existed in the world at that time.

And the second thing I think that people don't give enough count to is, you know those other things you skipped over in the history book, along with the tariffs and banking, all of the protest movements and this

agrarian discontent, that the tariffs were taxing the countryside in order to advantage the industrial areas and especially the owners of industry.

And people at the time noticed, and there was huge political instability as a result, that you had all of these protest movements now with all these picturesque names, but that the country was heading, and it was a period of extraordinary labor violence, violence of other kinds.

The tariff was the mother, in many ways, of those civil dissensions that then became much more peaceful in the years years when the United States moved to a freer trade system where the proceeds of growth were shared much more fairly than they were shared during the high tariff period.

Absolutely.

And you used that term mother.

The phrase at the time was the tariff is the mother of the trust.

So the tariff was not used to build up small businesses and increase employment.

It was really not designed, but certainly helped out big business and insulated them from foreign competition, led to higher prices, and that led to a progressive movement that really complained about that high level of taxation that helped the urban elites and hurt the rural poor.

I want to now move to a slightly later period.

This is a period that I think Americans of today know more about or hear more about, and that is the Great Depression and the famous Smoot Hawley tariff.

One of the things that, again, the apologists for high tariffs will say is, well, Smoot Hawley didn't cause the Great Depression.

The Great Depression had already begun when Smoot Hawley was imposed.

And anyway, trade was already collapsing anyway, so you can't blame Smooth Hawley for it.

So sorry, Wall Street Journal editorial page, which is always teaching people about Smoot Hawley.

The Smooth Hawley tariff, which you've written two books about, was not the culprit and something else was to blame.

What do you say to that error?

Well, it's certainly right.

I think that Smoot Hawley did not cause the Great Depression.

Milton Friedman wrote, and Anna Schwartz wrote a book on the monetary history of the United States and sort of conclusively showed that it was a monetary policy phenomenon, very deflationary policies pursued by the Fed, sort of under the gold standard.

But that doesn't mean it didn't have any impact whatsoever on the economy.

It did contract trade.

It did lead to foreign retaliation against U.S.

exports.

So it's not exactly a boom to the U.S.

economy.

It led to this downward spiral of world trade because other countries mimicked the U.S., not just in retaliating against us, but also in raising their own trade barriers.

So the trade to GDP ratio of the world shrank.

U.S.

exporters, both manufacturers and farmers, were locked out of foreign markets out of discrimination.

And Canada, one of our largest trading partners, really hit back at the U.S.

with retaliatory tariffs that hurt, once again, U.S.

agriculture and other industries.

So it was not a good thing for the United States.

And the question for economic historians has been, how much did it contribute to the Depression, not whether it was a major cause or provided some boost?

Well, I'm going to launch a theory of my own about how tariffs were to blame for the Great Depression, and tell me if you think this is too fanciful.

Because I do think

tariffs caused it, but not the Smoot-Hawley tariff of 1930.

It was the tariffs of the early 1920s.

And we hear less about them because, frankly, the Republicans of the Wall Street Journal who want to condemn Smoot Hawley also want to save the memory of the Republican presidents of the 1920s, Harding and Coolidge.

And so they don't want to remember the tariffs that those guys were responsible for.

But here's the story I would tell about where the Great Depression came from.

So the world emerges from the First World War with massive debts, both the debts to pay for the war and then the debts to pay for the reparations that Germany owed to make up for the damage Germany did to Belgium, to France, and to other countries.

So this enormous amount of debt, almost all of it owed to the United States, either directly or indirectly.

The countries that had been ravaged by the war, Germany, Belgium,

and France, and the countries that were left deeply indebted by the war, like Great Britain, the only way they could service those debts was by massive exports to the country to whom they owed the money, the United States.

That was what happened after World War II so successfully, that all the countries that had been left impoverished by the war exported to get the dollars to pay for the things they needed from the United States, not only food, but capital goods, and after the First World War to service the debts.

The United States did instead of letting them export was to impose in the early 1920s a pair of deadly tariffs.

Coming out of the Great Depression of 1919-1920, the world is hit by the war, it's hit by the flu epidemic, it's hit by the

1920 depression.

They need to export.

The United States lays on these massive tariffs.

Belgium, Germany, France, Britain, the others cannot export to the United States, but they still need the dollars.

So what do they do?

They borrow them.

They borrow them on a breathtaking scale.

So to the First World War debt, we add the whole new 1920s reconstruction debt, all of it forced by the inability to export to the United States.

They had to get dollars.

You either sell or you borrow.

They borrowed instead.

And it was that pileup of debt that was the necessary, not the direct cause of the Great Depression, but it was the precondition that when the Great Depression started, or when the recession started in 1929-30, that it was the match that was thrown on that giant pyre.

of pre-existing debt.

And that was the origin of the Great Depression.

Smoot Hawley made it worse.

But if you are not interested in saving the reputation of Calvin Coolidge and Herbert

and Warren Harding, you can face up to the

Fordney-McCumber tariffs of the 1920s should be as famous as Smoot Hawley.

And I think they're the culprit.

And so, well, not the Smoot Hawley tariff was to blame.

Tariffs in general were the cause.

And the people of the period after the Second World War knew that.

And that's why basically when you're rebuilding from World War II, Americans went to the big book on the library that said, what do we do in the 1910s and 1920s?

Let's do the opposite and see if it works better.

And it did.

The United States switched to a free trade policy, allowed the ravaged countries to export to the United States, and the result was the extraordinary expansion of growth.

What do you think of that fanciful theory?

No, actually, there's a lot to that.

In particular, identifying the Fortney-McCumber tariff of 1922 as being a big culprit for the instability in the 1920s, which of course fed into the 1930s.

So you're right, this is a period, this is an opportunity for the U.S.

Coming out of World War I.

We could have taken a different stance in terms of isolationism, protectionism, immigration policy.

Instead, what the Republican Party did is revert to where we had been in the late 19th century.

I mean, even William McKinley, who President Trump often refers to, he, as late as 1901, wanted to shift the Republicans and shift the country onto a different track in terms of trade policy.

We could have done that after World War I, and we did not.

We've reverted to form, we've raised tariffs, and you're absolutely right.

It made a bad situation worse.

It

compounded all the problems that Europe was facing.

You're absolutely right.

They had to earn dollars to pay back their debts during World War I.

We made that more difficult.

And the 1920s was maybe a roaring 20s for the U.S.

in part, but for most of Western Europe, it was not a good decade.

They were trying to recover, and we sort of squelched that effort.

And of course, when we have the monetary shocks of the

late 1920s, early 1930s, we're already in a bad situation and it just compounds the disaster.

Can I put in a little historical footnote here?

Everyone uses the phrase roaring 20s as if it was coined as a compliment.

And that's not true.

That's another mistake.

So the phrase roaring 20s, which referred to the big stock market booms of the 1920s, is actually a formation.

When you sail from, you go by sailing ship from Britain to Australia, as you round the lower left-hand corner of Australia, you pick up, you're at the 40th parallel.

of the Earth's geography.

And there are huge and very fast winds there.

And so sailors in the sailing ship days referred to this area underneath Australia as the Roaring 40s, that you went zoom, shooting along the southern shore of Australia from the lower left-hand corner around the porn where Melbourne and Sydney were.

But the Roaring 40s were also incredibly dangerous.

They roared because the winds literally roared.

And so when the stock market began to be whipped around by all the crazy tariffs and economic policies of the 1920s, nervous people, not as a compliment, called it the Roaring 20s in reference to this danger to sailing ships of the Roaring 40s underneath Australia.

And then, you know, we now think of it as, oh, it just meant good times for everybody.

The 20s are not a good time for American farmers at a time when half the country lived on agriculture.

And they were not a good time for American export industries, which found European markets lost to them.

Certain industries benefited.

There was the new technology of the automobile, the new technology of the radio.

But I think there's just a lot of myth-making here that a period that was unstable and ended in disaster

gets remembered too fondly because people have forgotten about the sailing ship, which is where it got its name from.

Right.

I agree.

It's a very misleading metaphor for the U.S.

economy in the 1920s because, as you point out so appropriately, the farm sector, which is a third to half of the U.S.

economy, did very poorly during that decade.

They had a lot of debts coming out of World War I.

They had overexpanded.

They lost markets with the recovery.

And the smooth hauling tariff, in some sense, was some very poorly designed attempt to help out farmers.

Of course, it wouldn't have been able to do that, and it didn't do that.

But the economy was not doing so well for a lot of Americans in the 1920s.

All right, let me pick up with a third historical episode, and that's one closer to the present.

So the Chinese communists come out of the disasters of Mao Zedong's rule and decide to reform their economy.

At first, they do it cautiously and slowly, first confined to the farm sector, then they move to industry.

But by the 1990s, they're allowing private property, private management in industry as well as farming, and they're beginning to become an export power.

And they become very much a rapid export power after the year 2000.

Goods pour out of China to the rest of the world.

And a paper published in the early 2010s looked at the areas that were exposed to Chinese imports in the early 2000s.

David Autor, I believe, is the name of the principal author of the paper, I believe there are others,

and wrote a paper called The China Shock.

So let's talk, can we talk about the China shock?

We are invited to believe that Americans are worse off today than they were 30 years ago because of trade.

You and I were there.

It doesn't seem true if you were there and remember what it was like, but tell us about the China shock and what lesson should we really learn.

Well, first of all, your characterization of the paper is absolutely right.

They're looking at relative differences across different regions of the country, not looking at sort of whether overall employment's going up or overall employment's going down, which is often how it's interpreted.

But you're right.

So the Tiny Shock, sort of there are two phases to it: the 1990s, and then the 2000, 2008 period in particular is when there's a big ramp up in U.S.

imports from China.

In some sense, they're absolutely right.

If we're importing more of certain labor-intensive goods, we'd expect those industries located in the United States to do relatively poorly.

They're facing a lot more competition.

And we saw that with apparel.

Apparel employment goes way down.

Of course, apparel employment is relatively low-wage employment located in the south.

But I think one of the things they highlighted was that it's the regional concentration of those impacts of Chinese imports that proved particularly important.

But once again, that's missing the overall picture for what's happening to the overall economy.

During the 2000s, coming out of the recession of 2000, 2001, the unemployment rate is going down during this period of the China shock.

We have many industries expanding employment.

So this is not exactly a period of the whole economy is being ravaged by China.

It's very much there's certain particular sectors and certain parts of the country that are not doing well, but the country overall was doing reasonably well.

In fact, it's only in retrospect that we sort of identify the China shock.

At the time, a lot of firms were not filing anti-dumping complaints against Chinese imports.

A lot of labor groups were not really upset about what China was doing.

So it's only in retrospect we see, aha, that maybe Chinese imports played a bigger role during that period than when we thought.

One thing that's missing, too, in a lot of the studies here is the important role of the exchange rate.

The U.S.

had urged China in the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis, the late 1990s, not to depreciate or devalue its currency.

So they did that because the U.S.

requested that and they kept it fixed.

Arguably, this is a time when the renminbi should have been appreciating rather than remaining fixed.

And I think that that had a bigger role to play in terms of how we think about that period than sometimes suggested.

Yeah, this gets one of my biggest, maybe my single biggest grievance or complaint about how trade policy is misrepresented to people who don't study it closely.

So the story that we're invited to believe, and it's a story story that goes back to writers about trade going back to Roman times, is that literally Roman times, what happens is you have a lot of extravagance in the imperial capital.

Blame especially the women.

And they want foreign fripperies and foreign luxuries.

And because they want more, all these foreign fripperies and foreign luxuries, they import too much.

And because they import too much, capital leaves the country and you get poor.

But

the story is always told that the driver is trade.

And this is ultimately a moral story of overconsumption.

And in the modern terms, I say, look, we have all these big deficits, and most people don't know, not only does Trump, but his Vice President Vance, who reads books, often either accidentally or willfully mixes up the trade deficit and the fiscal deficit.

The fiscal deficit is how much does the government tax?

How much does the government spend?

Trade is how much merchandise does the United States bring into the country?

How much merchandise does it sell out?

The trade deficit often overlooks the fact that, you know, when the United States sells insurance abroad, that's an export.

When foreign students come to the United States to study in American universities, that's also an export.

That's a way of earning money on international markets.

It's confusing because you're earning it on your own soil.

But in fact, you are selling to foreigners.

They just come to you.

Tourism in the same way.

They come to you to consume the benefit, but it's one, a benefit you are selling to foreigners.

So if exports are good, Those are also exports, although trade deficits don't always properly account for them because people often focus on the merchandise trade deficit, not the whole balance of goods and services.

But they always want to tell this moral story of you overconsume and therefore you get capital flows.

When the truth, and this is my grievance, is the story is really the other way around oftentimes, that the United States borrows a lot.

And because it borrows a lot, partly for good reasons, it's the most attractive place in the world to invest, so capital flows in in order to invest in American industry, which is good.

But also governments, especially the present one, do not tax as much as they want to spend.

And so, again, it has to suck in capital to fund the government.

And when capital flows in, well, you tell us what happens next.

Well, when capital comes in, we have a quote-unquote capital account surplus where foreign residents are buying U.S.

assets.

They're buying U.S.

assets rather than buying U.S.

goods.

So we'll have a current account deficit.

That is, we'll have a deficit on our trade and goods and services.

Although, as you point out correctly, we have a surplus.

We're a net exporter of services.

It's not enough to counteract the goods deficit, but we'll have a deficit on trade and goods that is the mirror image of that capital inflow to the U.S.

because, once again, the U.S.

rate of return on assets is very high.

We're a very safe country to invest, and foreign residents want to invest in the U.S.

So, my grievance here, and this is one that goes way back in U.S.

history, is that we either have trade surpluses or trade deficits.

And what's interesting is in the 1960s, there's so many people in the U.S.

complaining about the U.S.

trade surplus.

Because once again, if you take that mirror image, what that means is capital is leaving the U.S.

U.S.

multinationals are making investments in Europe and elsewhere.

And people were complaining, why aren't multinationals investing in the U.S.?

Why are we investing in other countries?

So my view has always been, it doesn't matter whether you run a trade surplus or trade deficit, people are going to complain.

Either that foreigners are buying up too much of our assets or we're not investing enough home and we're selling, you know, buying assets abroad.

But set that aside, is we blame trade on other countries.

We're not to blame at all.

So the fact that we have large fiscal deficits, actually, that is related to our trade deficit.

If we want to reduce the trade deficit, reducing the U.S.

fiscal deficit would be one one thing we could do to address that problem.

But going back to Thomas Jefferson, one of the first reports he issued is Secretary of State, complaining about all the policies of other countries that affect U.S.

trade without looking at what are we doing with respect to trade.

It's easier to blame the other guy than ourselves.

I worked for a while for Bob Bartley at Wall Street Journal, and although I complained a little bit earlier about the journal and its valorization of Harding and Coolidge, nonetheless, they have been heroes of the fight for free trade and against Trump, too.

They've been very outspoken.

So kudos to them for that.

But somebody once asked Bob Bartley, what should the United States do about the trade deficit?

And he said, very simple.

I have a very direct plan that will completely address the problem.

I think we should stop collecting the statistics.

Yes.

And he would then go on to explain, you know who has the biggest trade deficit of any place on earth?

Manhattan Island.

Everything flows in.

And the United States, Manhattan,

it doesn't send ball bearings out.

It doesn't send steel plate.

But somehow, Manhattan Island Island manages to keep on making a living because it is making things that the world wants, intellectual products, insurance, advertising, all kinds of non-tangible goods.

And in return, the planet sends it fruits and vegetables and fancy sofas and subway cars and everything that is consumed on Manhattan Island.

But the real point here is when, as Trump does, you incur, put the United States on a path to unprecedented peacetime borrowing ever, you are guaranteeing that that that is going to be equalized by the collapse of American exports into the world.

Absolutely, absolutely.

And I was going to say, what is true in Manhattan is true in my little town here of Hanover, New Hampshire.

We don't produce cars, we don't produce carpeting, we don't produce just about any of the goods we consume here.

We have a reasonable standard of living because we export educational services here at Dartmouth.

And so, once again, that trade enables us to consume a lot more because we specialize in one activity and export as a result of that.

I just want to say something about the Wall Street Journal, too.

In addition to not collecting the statistics, and I said that it's absolutely right.

If we didn't collect economic statistics, we would still know if there's inflation.

We'd see it every day.

We'd still know if the economy is doing well or not, GDP growth.

We'd feel it in terms of our own jobs and income.

If we had a trade deficit or surplus, I don't think we'd know.

It's only because we have the statistics that we'd know.

But my favorite one line from the Wall Street Journal editorial page, also about the trade deficit is the line, the best way to think about the trade deficit is not to think about it.

And I think that's absolutely right.

There are other things we should be focusing on, getting our house in order, and then the trade deficit will solve itself.

There's a lot of the argument about trade is also, it seems to me, driven by nostalgia.

And you hear that especially from President Trump because he is so very old.

And I'm getting older too, so I'm not immune to this.

But those of us of a certain age grew up at a time when the important industries in America were steel, rubber, automobiles,

everything to do with that complex of things.

And the United States produces less of those items, which are basically 1920s technologies improved in the 1950s and 60s.

And to the extent that it produces them, it uses fewer and fewer people to produce them.

And so you have the spectacle of we're running the whole economy with an idea of, well, how do we get people working again in steel mills?

Or in President Trump's case, how do we get them back into the mines?

How do we drive them back into the coal mines?

This statistic is probably now even more extreme than when I began watching it in the first Trump years.

But back in the late 2010s, President Trump was always talking about coal miners.

And I did a quick calculation that if you towed up the entire coal mining sector, not just the miners, but like the bookkeepers,

everybody, everybody who works for everything to do with any coal mining company, you got to in like the early, late 2010s, a number of about 50,000 people, which is fewer than the number of people who are licensed by a state to teach yoga.

Not yoga instructors, those who have gone to the trouble of getting a yoga instructor license.

There's a lot of people.

So if I said, well, I I have an idea, why don't we completely mess up the U.S.

and world economy, make everything more expensive for everybody, and also subject ourselves to a lot of pollution and environmental degradation and climate change to protect the yoga instructors from competition.

That seems like a stupid or bizarre or off-boat idea, but because people have this memory of when coal mining was an enormous industry, hundreds of thousands, at one point, millions of people mined coal.

And the same way with steel, President Trump has allowed U.S.

Steel, which is now the second biggest steel company in the United States, not the biggest, to be acquired by a Japanese company.

But he made U.S.

Steel pay for this and the Japanese company pay for this by all kinds of direct presidential supervision of their decisions, including whether or not the company will stay based in Pittsburgh.

And this is all battening on the impression that many of us had, isn't steel like a really big employer in the United States?

Didn't it used to be until quite recently?

The idea, you know, almost no one anymore makes a living making steel.

There's still a lot of steel made, made, but the United States is still making a lot, a lot of steel, but with very, very, very few people.

So if your concern is employment, these are not the industries that employ people, but few of us understand what are the industries that employ people, and so we're vulnerable to these impressions.

Absolutely.

And you're right, picking steel is such a fascinating case to look at.

In the 1980s, it took 10 worker hours to produce a ton of steel.

Now, we actually produce just as much steel now as we did back then.

But now it takes one worker hour to produce a ton of steel.

So if you go back and look at those old black and white pictures of steel mills in the 50s and 60s, you'll see a lot of men coming in in the morning and leaving at night.

Now no one's coming in and out because it's all mechanized.

It's all technology.

You don't have physical labor doing it.

And in particular, the type of labor employed in steel mills has changed.

So before it was high school dropouts or high school graduates, now it's you have an advanced degree at Carnegie Mellon.

and you're an engineer and you're monitoring all the dials and making sure the equipment works well and looking at the software that's moving all the equipment.

So there's been that skill upgrading.

Certain towns like Pittsburgh have moved away from steel and done very well with higher education, health care, as a city, they've pivoted themselves.

But if you're in a smaller town that had a steel mill that shuts down, there's very few other opportunities unless you move out of town.

So that's the divide we're sort of facing.

Technology is changing.

We're still producing a lot of stuff, but we're just not using people to produce it anymore.

And it's the services around those industries that are providing the value added in some sense.

Yeah.

Well, I want to hit one last bugaboo of mine before

I say thank you to you.

So, one of the things the United States has recently done, or the Trump administration has recently done, is put a giant tariff on copper.

Now, copper is an indispensable ingredient to the electronic age.

Tiny amounts of copper show up in lots and lots of devices, but there are now so many devices that although the individual amounts of copper are very small, the collective amount of copper used is very large.

So, Secretary of Commerce Luttnick was on TV saying, we need copper.

Well, what if there's a war?

What if there's a war?

We need to make our own copper.

The United States only produces half of the copper it consumes, and we're vulnerable in war.

So, you go and look it up.

Well, where does the United States import copper from?

First, Chile, second, Canada, third, Peru.

That's 90% of U.S.

copper imports.

So, I don't know if the United States is planning to import copper, go to war with Chile.

I mean, if the United States does, then there will be a copper problem.

But assuming it does not go to war with Chile or Canada or Peru, then

what's the problem?

To which I think the answer is, well, Chinese submarines may intercept the flow of copper from Chile to the United States, and we will lose the war because we can't get crucial Chilean or Peruvian or Canadian copper through the sea lanes.

So that's interesting.

That's an interesting problem.

How did we cope with this during World War II?

I wonder if we were self-sufficient in copper in World War II.

And that's, no, it turns out in World War II, 1942, 43, 44, I posted a link to this from, it was old OSS data that's now on the the CIA website, and I found it and posted a link to it.

The United States imported almost exactly the same amount of its copper during World War II as it did today.

And the answer was, well, why didn't the Japanese submarines cut the sea lines?

The answer was because the United States controlled the sea.

And the problem that you need to solve for is not having copper mines inside the territorial confines.

Because I guarantee you, you can't have everything.

You can't have molybdenum.

You can't have nickel.

That's not going to, you know, you can't make every mineral that is found somewhere in the Earth's crust within this little piece of the Earth's crust.

A lot of it will have to travel by sea.

You have to control the sea.

And because the United States controlled the sea during World War II, it was not a problem to import copper.

And if the United States controls the sea in the next conflict, it will not be a problem.

And if the United States doesn't control the sea, it will have many problems of which copper will be the least.

And then the last commercial.

The way you control the sea is by having ships.

You know what ships are made of?

Steel.

And guess what the United States is tariffing and making more expensive?

Steel imports.

So we're not going to be able to get those either.

So that we are shrinking the future United States Navy in order to pay off President Trump's

political debts to the steel workers of Pennsylvania or his fantasies about what those industries used to be.

Yes, I mean, copper is a fascinating case too.

I mean, if we're really concerned about the supply of copper, we should be stockpiling it.

We shouldn't be draining America first.

I mean, if we impose a tariff, what that's saying is we're not going to take advantage of foreign sources of supply now when there's not a war.

We're going to start mining ourselves and depleting our own reserves.

Presumably, we want to keep that in the ground for a future time when we need it.

And we should be using a lot of foreign copper right now.

We should be stockpiling it, not depleting what we have of our own scarce reserves.

But you're right, it's just a boneheaded policy.

Well, the copper policy, I assume, is not totally boneheaded, because I assume the real thing that is going on is somebody who owns a copper mine inside the United States bought a lot of Trump meme coins.

And in return for buying a lot of Trump meme coins, the Trump administration is making sure that the owner of this copper mine won't have to face Chilean price competition.

And then they invoke all this world, this misremembered history of World War II to justify what is essentially a payoff, I assume, to someone who's been generous to the Trump team.

Well, that points to another problem that you've pointed out too with Trump tariff policy is the openness to corruption.

I mean, here we're having, if we're really just helping out a few copper miners in the U.S.

or copper firms, we're not thinking about strategically what is best.

in the national interest.

We're saying trade policy is up for highest bidder.

Whoever buys meme coin or what have you, you have a say in U.S.

trade policy.

And what you didn't mention in highlighting those three suppliers of copper, Canada, Chile, and Peru, we have free trade agreements with all of them.

They're allies.

They've been reliable partners and suppliers.

And to impose a major tariff on something they're supplying to us at this juncture is just ripping up our foreign relations as well as our economic relationship with those countries.

Well, when you talk about also this industrial, this flow of corruption, one of the points you so powerfully make in the early sections of Clashing Over Commerce is once you start tariffing things, you create these perverse incentives through the whole economy.

Because you put a tariff in the olden days on wool.

Well, suddenly American coats are more expensive than other people's coats.

So you have to put a tariff on coat and you get this house that Jack built problem.

And that every time you put a tariff on something, you render all those who use that something non-competitive with their foreign competitors.

And so tariffs then tend to ramify until the whole economy is completely uncompetitive with the rest of the the world.

Yeah, and we see that today with steel by raising the price of those inputs.

Now, you and I don't go out to Home Depot or Lowe's every weekend and buy a bar of steel, but Ford and GM and Caterpillar and John Deere, they buy a lot of steel.

And we're raising their costs, costs that their foreign competitors don't have to pay, and making them less competitive in the U.S.

market and in the export markets around the world.

How do you help them out?

Do you intervene with more tariffs or do you just sort of rethink the policy?

I wish we'd do a rethink.

Yeah.

Well, I don't think there's a lot of thinking that explains this policy.

There's a lot of feeling.

There's a lot of manipulation.

There are people who benefit and they know exactly what they're doing.

And then there are others who just are caught up in obsolete ideas and prejudices.

And then there are just a lot of interest groups, including ideological interest groups, that are flowing a lot of money.

into this space to get people to do things that are really self-harming.

You mentioned earlier that Canada and Chile and Peru are allies with with whom the United States has free trade agreements.

Well, those free trade agreements have been ripped up.

And in many ways, I'm speaking to you from Canada right now.

I don't know that Canadians right now think of the United States as an ally.

I don't know what Chilean public opinion is looking like, but I would suspect not that favorable either.

And that the United States is being pushed into a path that is going to be very costly, aside from the cost that consumers are going to feel when they go to the supermarket next week and pay the new 17% tariff on Mexican tomatoes that is there, again,

because some Trump supporter grows tomatoes and doesn't want to face Mexican price competition.

Yeah, there you go.

Florida has distorted U.S.

trade policy quite a bit between the winter vegetables, Florida tomato producers, Florida sugar producers account for a lot of U.S.

sugar policy.

So all's not well in Florida in some sense.

And Trump just imposed a tariff on Brazil so that they wouldn't punish their president who tried to make a coup d'état.

I believe Brazil is the largest supplier of orange juice in the United States.

So get ready to pay more for that.

Tariffs, if we would just, we need another word maybe because people don't know what it means.

If we could call it an import tax or just you pay more, you pay more, and some privileged few

get a respite from having to face price competition because you are forced to pay more.

I've been reading a lot of Ronald Reagan's speeches on trade this summer, and the eloquence and the force with which he embraced free trade is just really inspiring.

And he said, we shouldn't call it protectionism.

We should call it destructionism because it really is destructive.

And it's not just economically destructive, as you point out with respect to Canada.

We alienate friends and lose potential allies with this trade policy in the mere hope of trying to bring back a few jobs in this sector or that sector without looking at domestic consumer impacts, without looking at the impact on other countries.

So it's very short-sighted.

Well, and as I said, the people, not everyone is short-sighted.

The people who are raising tariffs on the people who buy tomatoes, buy orange juice, juice, buy knives and forks, buy their things at Home Depot, are doing it in part to finance the giant tax cut that the president just passed in his big fiscal bill.

They are not short-sighted.

They are very clear-sighted.

What is going on here in great part is simply moving the burden of paying for government from those most able to pay through those least able to pay.

And the people who are doing that are doing it very deliberately and very clear-sightedly.

I don't know how clear-sighted President Trump is exactly on this issue.

He may be blinded by his own ignorance.

But, you know, he's noticing, too, that this is in his interest, and

he will be among those who benefit from this recalibration, this repositioning of American, the cost of American government from those who can most afford to pay to those who can least afford to pay.

Yes, I mean, there have been a lot of studies done by economists about how regressive tariffs are, because as you sort of point out or implicit in your comment was

lower-income groups spend more of their income, a greater share of their income on traded goods.

at Home Depot, at Kohl's, buying apparel or what have you.

They're the ones who are going to bear the price, pay pay the tax, as we open the discussion.

What is a tariff?

It is a tax, and it does raise domestic prices of those goods that are affected by the tax, and it happens to be a very regressive tax.

The tax cuts will be regressive as well in a different way, but the tariffs will hit lower income households more than higher income households, to be sure.

You mentioned Ronald Reagan, and I think one of the reasons Reagan was so impassioned.

was so impassioned on the subject was because, of course, he had lived through the Depression.

He remembered what tariffs had done to a generation of Americans.

I hope we don't have to learn that lesson in our time through the same hard teaching as Ronald Reagan's generation had to learn it.

Doug Irwin, thank you so much for joining the David Frum Show.

It was such a pleasure to have you.

What I learned so much from you every time I read you, every time I speak to you, I'm so grateful.

Well, thank you very much for having me, and the feeling is mutual.

I learned so much from your writing, so thank you.

Thank you so much.

Bye-bye.

This episode is brought to you by Progressive Insurance.

Do you ever find yourself playing the budgeting game?

Well, with the name Your Price tool from Progressive, you can find options that fit your budget and potentially lower your bills.

Try it at Progressive.com.

Progressive Casualty Insurance Company and Affiliates.

Price and Coverage Match Limited by State Law.

Not available in all states.

Attention, all small biz owners.

At the UPS store, you can count on us to handle your packages with care.

With our certified packing experts, your packages are properly packed and protected.

And with our pack and ship guarantee, when we pack it and ship it, we guarantee it.

Because your items arrive safe or you'll be reimbursed.

Visit the ups store.com/slash guarantee for full details.

Most locations are independently owned.

Product services, pricing, and hours of operation may vary.

See Center for Details.

The UPS store.

Be unstoppable.

Come into your local store today.

Thank you so much to Douglas Irwin for joining me today on the David Frum Show.

Thanks to all of you for watching.

I hope you will share, subscribe, like this program on any platform you use, whether you watch or whether you listen.

We depend on you, our listeners and viewers, to help the program grow.

If you want to support the work of the David Frum Show and all of my colleagues at The Atlantic, the best way to do that is by subscribing to The Atlantic.

And I thank you for those who have already done that.

I want to thank my friends at the Picton Gazette for allowing me the hospitality of this office here in Picton, Ontario.

And I want to thank my wife, Danielle Fromm, who created the studio you see all around you, the flowers, the photograph, the banner.

That's all her work.

And I thank her.

And I thank you for joining and look forward to seeing you again here next week.

This episode of The David Frum Show was produced by Nathaniel Fromm and edited by Andrea Valdez.

It was engineered by Dave Grime.

Our theme is by Andrew M.

Edwards.

Claudine Abaid is the executive producer of Atlantic Audio, and Andrea Valdez is our managing editor.

I'm David Frum.

Thank you for listening.