
Richard Hanania - Foreign Policy, Fertility, and Wokeness
Richard Hanania is the President of the Center for the Study of Partisanship and Ideology and the author of Public Choice Theory and the Illusion of Grand Strategy: How Generals, Weapons Manufacturers, and Foreign Governments Shape American Foreign Policy.
Watch on YouTube. Listen on Apple Podcasts, Spotify, or any other podcast platform.
Episode website here.
Follow Richard on Twitter. Follow me on Twitter for updates on future episodes.
Read Richard's Substack: https://richardhanania.substack.com/
Timestamps:
(0:00:00) - Intro
(0:04:35) - Did war prevent sclerosis?
(0:06:05) - China vs America's grand strategy
(0:10:00) - Does the president have more power over foreign policy?
(0:11:30) - How to deter bad actors?
(0:15:39) - Do some countries have a coherent foreign policy?
(0:16:55) - Why does self-interest matter in foreign but not domestic policy?
(0:21:05) - Should we limit money in politics?
(0:23:47) - Should we credit expertise for nuclear detante and global prosperity?
(0:28:45) - Have international alliances made us safer?
(0:31:57) - Why does academic bueracracy work in some fields?
(0:36:26) - Did academia suck even before diversity?
(0:39:34) - How do we get expertise in social sciences?
(0:42:19) - Why are things more liberal?
(0:43:55) - Why is big tech so liberal?
(0:47:53) - Authoritarian populism vs libertarianism
(0:51:40) - Can authoritarian governments increase fertility?
(0:54:54) - Will increasing fertility be dysgenic?
(0:56:43) - Will not having kids become cool?
(0:59:22) -Advice for libertarians?
Get full access to Dwarkesh Podcast at www.dwarkesh.com/subscribe
Listen and Follow Along
Full Transcript
So there's this idea on the populist right that we tried libertarianism, and now wokeness has taken over. And I'm like, okay, when did Republicans repeal the Civil Rights Act? When did that happen? When did they defund public education? No, you actually haven't done anything close to libertarianism.
And now you're making libertarianism the scapegoat for all these negative trends. Today I'm speaking with Richard Hemenia, who is the president of the Center for the Study of Partisanship and Ideology, and the author of the new book, Public Choice Theory and the Illusion of Grand Strategy.
So Richard, first, can you just summarize the book briefly before we get into the questions? Sure. So the argument of my book is, it has two real audiences.
So first, people who study international relations, political scientists, there's something in there for them. And there's also, I think, something in there for people who are just interested in American foreign policy more generally.
So the way that academics tend to study foreign policy, and this is a simplification, but if you're going to have to generalize about the way sort of it's understood in political science, the field of international relations, the idea is that states basically are rational actors, and rational actors doesn't mean what they do is necessarily good for the world, or whether their values are consistent with other people's values, but basically that states seek certain goals, and their behavior can be understood in that context. So basically, the study of grant strategy is sort of a corollary of this and the idea is that diplomatic, economic, and military means tend to be put towards the same goals.
They're all basically moving in the same direction. And I think this view of understanding foreign policy is sort of naive.
my main argument is that we don't think like this in terms of domestic policy. We don't think that there's a grand strategy of the U.S.
government with regards to immigration, with regards to health care, with regards to tax system. It's sort of a, there's a fallacy of seeing it designed in international, kind of a design in international relations or kind of a, you know, a kind of a sort of goal-focused behavior and we tend not to make that mistake in other areas.
So that's, you know, the first two chapters are basically the theoretical case for why a lot of the ways we look at international relations is wrong. That people are interested in academic works, they're interested in sort of thinking about ideas and political philosophy, I think people will enjoy those chapters.
And then most of the rest of the book is basically looking at American foreign policy and asking, does a theory of grad strategy or a theory based on public choice, which I present as an alternative model, does that explain things like when the U.S. troop presence is abroad, when we start and end various wars, the American sanctions regime, so major parts of American foreign policy.
And I argue that the public choice model of foreign policy just works better. So maybe the unitary actor model is not right right now, but wouldn't be true in the future.
So, you know, like the countries that have a fucked up foreign policy where the whole thing is in shambles and contradicts itself, you know, they'll lose out to the countries that actually have a cohesive national strategy.
And in the long run, the countries that actually do have a cohesive agrarian strategy will win, right?
Yeah, so this is actually one of the arguments for how you get rationality that I take issue with.
I think this is most closely associated with international relations theorist Kenneth Waltz. You know, there's a few things you can say about this, right? Like, so, you know, it might just go against the nature of the state, right? Maybe the state is such a big and complicated thing that maybe you get closer to rationality, you get closer to grand strategies through a sort of a selection process, but it's still an open question how close you get.
You know, and the other thing is, I would say that there's a lot else going on in the world beyond how states react to one another. So, you know, there's, you know, the origins of economic development are a complicated thing, and a state can have, a country like the United States can have a lot going for it as far as human capital as far as institutions and do very well economically and then you know just and it can afford to have a sort of irrational foreign policy there's actually the one one one possibility is that states that tend to have good institutions for economic growth, things like decentralization, individual freedom, an open society, that might be bad for forming a grand strategy for international relations because you can have interest groups influence foreign policy and people are worried about their own lives rather than what's going on abroad and the state is limited and can't really enforce its will.
So this is a possibility that, you know, nobody's brought up before, but perhaps, you know, there
is some kind of tension there where states with bad foreign policies will tend to have good
economic growth and therefore a lot of geopolitical strength.
Interesting. So it's one way to read your book that maybe the decline of war has been bad,
right? Because when you had war, you know, I've got the casualties and everything, that's bad.
But at least you had to keep countries on their toes and their political institutions couldn't
Thank you. your book that maybe the decline of war has been bad, right? Because when you had war, you know, I've got the casualties and everything, that's bad.
But at least you had to keep countries on their toes and their political institutions couldn't become all messed up. So it's like, it's one way to read your book that the political institutions in our world have become so sclerotic because there isn't enough war.
I mean, so, you know, there's not a war is, you know, on balance bad, but are there good things we can say for war sort of as far as historical development goes? I think that, you know, depending on your politics, if you look at World War I and World War II, a lot happened for the expansion of the American federal government. And I think that's mostly been bad.
But if somebody thinks that's good, if you're a big supporter of the welfare state and sort of the centralization of power in Washington, you know, you have to credit World War I and World War II. I think that's clear from the historical record.
So unquestionably, war leads to changes. You know, the potential for war probably was part of the Cold War and eventually the Soviet Union collapsed.
If there was no potential for any kind of conflict there, who knows, maybe the Soviet Union could have existed forever. So unquestionably, war is an accelerant and a sort of catalyst for change, and if you think we need a lot of change, maybe you might distress seeing the decline of war over time, but change can also go in a negative direction too.
Now to what extent are these problems unique to democracy? So concentrated interests, being able to pull a government to do counterproductive things, because if you look at the quote unquote China's grand strategy, it's a very centralized system, there's one guy at the top, but they you know, they're doing some very stupid things, like they're fighting over some irrelevant islands with Japan. You know, they're getting into skirmishes with India over some mountain regions, um, and, you know, we'll see about the Belt and Road, but, you know, right now it seems like there's some place, you wouldn't know more about this than me, but there seems like there's some places where there's cost overruns and where, you know, they're building stuff in places that are relevant.
Um, so to what extent are centralized governments able to have a better grant strategy? So, yeah, we should be careful not to say, you know, having a grant strategy is better or smarter in some ways. Just the question that I address in the book is whether it's coherent.
Whether China, so we can understand China in comparison to the U.S. on these two axes, whether it's, you know, smart or wise versus whether it's coherent.
Whether it's smart or wise, which I think your question was getting at, I mean, China's blunders and having squabbles with Japan over a few islands, I mean, if you compare that to the U.S. investment in Afghanistan or Iraq, I mean, there's really, we're not really once a talk about foreign policy blunders.
I mean, the Chinese spending on the military is pretty low. I mean, there's really, you know, we're not really wants to talk about, you know, foreign policy blunders.
I mean, the Chinese spending on the military is pretty low. I mean, there's nothing that compares to Iraq, Afghanistan, Libya, Syria.
I mean, so we have blunder after blunder. And whether it's a Chinese, but whether the Chinese system has more coherence in foreign policy and whether that can be attributed to it not being a democracy.
I think that, right. I mean, I think that the fact that China's grand strategy has been not to have much of a foreign policy relative to the U.S., not to care much about what goes on in most of the world.
And then there does seem to be a concerted effort to sort of push out or push it upward and push its weight around within its region, which is natural, which is what states do as they tend to grow. And so, you know, when I look at Chinese foreign policy, do I see more coherence than American? Yes.
I mean, you don't see, you know, you see China basically inflict the punishment of a nation and there is usually a goal, right? And then you can usually, you know, so for example, Lithuania, I think just, I don't know if they recognized Taiwan or they did something with Taiwan. China didn't like it, so China did something against Lithuania.
I don't know if Lithuania has responded or whatever, but basically, I mean, you can understand how this makes sense, right? When the U.S. sanctions somebody, it basically says, you know, we're not going to recognize this government.
It destroys the economy. It's more total than anything China does anything China does and then it never talks to them again and you know that that's basically the end of it so yeah I mean that there's there's certainly more coherence and I think more sense to what China is doing than what the US is doing but to what extent is that just because you know China isn't powerful enough or doesn't have enough money to waste on debacles like Afghanistan and Iraq so like maybe in like 30 years when or not even 30 years, but like once our economy is bigger than ours, right? Will they be making the same kinds of mistakes? I mean, if you look at when was the British Empire most overextended, you know, the peak of colonization was when they weren't fully a democracy, right? Yeah, so I mean, so countries even without a lot of resources can often put a lot of efforts overseas.
So Maoist China, I think was one of the, you know, at least for its per capita level was the biggest provider of foreign aid in the world. By far it was giving us money for like subsidies in Eastern Europe for countries that were richer than itself.
So Maoist China was extremely poor and had an extremely interventionist foreign policy that it invested a lot in. Russia today over-invested foreign policy, you know, relative to its economic size.
So, you know, the U.S. certainly can't afford to do more than China.
And by PPP terms, I mean, China has caught up or passed the United States. So China, I mean, has the potential to do a lot more.
I just think it chooses not to.
Right.
Now, you say in the book that the public doesn't really care that much about foreign policy, at least in comparison to domestic policy. Does that mean that if the president actually did have a coherent vision of a grand strategy, he could enact it? Because the public is just not going to be paying attention.
And if he just really wants something, he could do it? I think it depends on the costs of what the grand strategy are. The grand strategy involves sending a lot of troops abroad and taking a lot of casualties, that's going to be really hard.
If it's more along the lines of we're going to crush one nation, and how we define grand strategy, there's grand strategy at the macro level, and then there's sort of at the end. We can think about it as an approach to one country.
we do see that like I think the the last administration had a de facto basically not a de facto even more than a de facto sort of an intended policy of regime change towards Iran and that wasn't that they weren't open about that but the idea was basically you just you know you just sanction them as much as possible and you just hope you know they're as less powerful as possible and potentially collapse and there was a more official strategy of regime change and they even recognized a different government in Venezuela and you know that didn't require any American casualties it required a lot of suffering in the countries that were then were targeted but it does seem that the American efforts were put towards certain goals. So yes, you're right, within certain limits, presidents do have freedom to do a lot.
And people don't care about Iran, and they don't care about that as well. So there was a lot of, yeah, there was a lot of freedom there.
Okay. Now you say sanctions don't work, intervention doesn't work, but if you look at a country like North Korea, we feel like, you know, if there was something, we really ought to be able to, we really ought to do it, like we really don't want them to have nukes or the capacity to launch nukes to the United States so if these traditional interventions don't work is there something you could do about a country like North Korea or like you know Venezuela is like starving its own people obviously sanctions are making it worse but like if you wanted to you know get rid of Maduro is there something we could do that it's like feasible and it's notctive? So, I mean, each of these cases is sort of unique.
So, I mean, North Korea, I mean, interventions work. I mean, if you just overthrow a government, you can get rid of them.
But obviously that would be very costly in the case of North Korea for nuclear weapons and even conventional weapons. They have a lot of, you know know a pretty big army um yeah can we do something about um north korean you know nukes um i think you know one one school of thought is basically that uh that north korea um wants nukes because it's afraid of the u.s right it's it's basically defensive it thinks that the u.s if not if it's not going to invade it at this point it's because of nukes but they would like to see the regime fall anyway and that's probably that's probably true and you know and the question is do you you know and then the question is do you accommodate sort of that fear if what you're worried about is nuclear weapons and you learn to live with the government now there's another school of thought of North Korea that says basically they want the U.S.
out and they want to they want to conquer the South. You know I don't have insight into the thinking of the North Korean regime so it's really hard to say which is the you know which is the correct position.
And then in Venezuela like is there something we can do to you know counteract the you know the terrible economic policies that the the Maduro regime, Shabez regime have implemented, it's very, very hard. I think the move towards more open markets globally has been the result of basically people seeing that markets work much better than central planning.
I mean the Soviet Union, the elites in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe realized that what they were doing was not working and they basically they moved to a capitalist system. It wasn't because Gorbachev, you know, wasn't forced into it.
There was nothing, there was no like rebellion from below or civil war or anything. They just basically decided that the regime had lost legitimacy even if not from the people, at least from those at the top, especially for the Soviet satellites.
And so that doesn't mean that that movement is going to be consistent in the direction of markets all the time everywhere. So you have to understand sometimes some places are going to go in the opposite direction.
I think one well, you know, one thing the U.S. does have to do some very harmful things to Latin America that I think they probably shouldn't do.
I mean, the drug war. I mean, these countries, so much of their politics revolves around stopping the flow of drugs because that's what the U.S.
demands.
And like, you know, who cares about drugs? Is that worth having a civil war over?
No, of course not. And, you know, Mexico and these other countriesin america would probably be much better off if we didn't uh if we didn't do that um i think that there's also a sense of a lot of u.s meddling as far as like democratization and human rights which people think these are generally good things and all else being equal they might be good things but we are not in a position to know you know like like if you're a country that has a serious violence problem, right, and that's like, you know, the first, you know, that's the prerequisite to everything else, to peaceful living, to growth, to everything is getting violent and under control, and Latin American countries have really bad problems with it, and then somebody comes from abroad and says, you know, you have to fight crime or you have to fight cartels in a way consistent with our human rights norms, you know, that's something that sounds good, but might not actually be conducive to getting the best possible policy at the local level.
So I think there's a lot of meddling and sort of hubris about what we know and what's best for these countries. And I think that moving away from that would probably help them solve their problems in their own way.
Now, you say in the book that one of the agents that are influencing American foreign policy are foreign governments, like Israel and Saudi Arabia. But if they are able to actually influence American policy in a way that is good for them as a nation, doesn't that make these countries rational actors then that have a cohesive grant strategy? Yeah, I mean, so something I don't go into the book is, and well, I mean, you have just talked about it now, sort of what countries, when countries have, you know, can act like more like unitary actors and when they don't.
And in the case of, I think that one of the determinants of whether a country acts with, you know, a strategy in a certain domain is how important the issue is to them, right? So Iran is much more important to Israel and Saudi Arabia than it is to America by many, many times. And so you can imagine Israel and Saudi Arabia do have something resembling a strategy when it comes to Iran.
And the U.S. has a sort of open political system and is liable to be influenced by those countries.
And often it's not even, you know, you could even question whether it's always those countries or it's a faction within those countries. But, yeah, I do take the point that, you know, often there's something closer to a strategy in what other countries are doing just because they're closer to the problem and it actually just matters a lot more to them.
And in the book, you say that when it comes to foreign policy, special interests matter more than ideas. And then ideas are after the fact justifications for what these special interests want.
But when you talk about domestic policy, you seem to be making the opposite point, that actually it's the ideology that matters more. And then economic self-interest actually determines very little about people's political preferences.
So why is there a difference between foreign policy and domestic policy? So my view on domestic policy, I mean, so there's, you know, at the level of the voter, there's, I think, very little in terms of objective interest because the voter doesn't have a stake in, you know, a stake in their vote doesn't determine the outcome of the election. So one of the consistent findings of political science is basically that people's economic circumstances do a very, very poor job of predicting their political orientation.
So whether you're a Republican or a Democrat or whatever, your economic situation is not very predictive, not even close compared to demographic factors and cultural attitudes and things like that. Now, when it comes to policy, I think there's a few different kinds of policy.
So most things, there is, you know, the public opinion is just not paying attention to. This public opinion has a really strong view on the nature of the tax code or, you know, the exact details of environmental regulations or, you know, whatever.
I mean, the same thing in foreign policy with, you know, something like NATO expansion. I think this is basically both international and domestic
international relations I mean, the same thing in foreign policy with, you know, something like NATO expansion. The, you know, so I think this is basically, you know, both international and domestic relations and domestic politics.
The interest groups, you know, have a huge role to play. Now, when it comes to certain issues that are particularly salient, so in the domestic context, this is something like Social Security, like people aren't going to notice like if you cut their social security benefits or their Medicare or something like that.
You know, there's not a lot of taxes, you know, same thing. There's not a lot of issues that are exactly like this.
But here public opinion matters and here you have to tread carefully if you're a politician. And it's the same thing in foreign policy when there's a cost that when you're going to do something that's potentially very costly to the country and it becomes a major political issue, then public opinion matters a lot more.
So you need public opinion to be on your side to go into Iraq, right? There was overwhelming support for the Iraq war at the time. Now, one of the unique things I think about foreign policy that gives leaders sort of more freedom of movement compared to domestic politics politics.
And if you're going to say what's the difference in sort of my understanding of politics between domestic issues and international issues, this is probably one of the most important. It's the fact that basically public opinion is more easily manipulated by leaders in foreign relations.
I don't think there's a way to, getting rid of Social Security that's going to work with the American public. You could easily sell some countries in threat to the United States because most Americans don't have experience with foreign countries.
They don't have independent knowledge. You know, these places like Ukraine or Russia or Estonia or anything is basically exists as an abstraction.
And why we think of one country as a friend and one country as an ally and one country as an enemy I mean that's basically that's media coverage that signals coming from elites and so it's you know you look at like going back to the Iraq war I mean nobody was thinking about attacking Iraq you know right after 9-11 but basically the Bush administration had you know high approval ratings in the aftermath of the attack. There was a full-on, basically, PR campaign to not explicitly tie Saddam to 9-11, but basically tie him to Al-Qaeda, you know, to make people be afraid of WMDs.
I mean, even though the Bush administration never said this, I mean, there was a I think it was a majority or a plurality of the public actually believes Saddam was personally involved in 9-11, which there was never any evidence for. But it was easy to sort of lead people in that direction, just because who knows anything about Saddam Hussein or Iraq, right? People have to sort of trust their leaders on these things.
And maybe that's getting harder as polarization is more extreme and people don't trust their leaders anymore. But there's still just more room to maneuver on foreign policy than there is on a lot of domestic issues.
You see in the book near the end that one of the ways to fix this should be that we better regulate a foreign lobbyist in the government and, you know, funding of, you know, let's say, defense contractors onto think tanks and research institutions. Do you think the same should be true of domestic policy? So we should limit the, I mean, this is kind of a leftist agenda of limiting how much money there is in politics, or is this unique to foreign policy? So, I mean, I sort of throw those ideas out there as sort of institutional fixes that people can think about.
I am, you know, I am not, you know, I don't think I come down and say, you know, this is something to fix it. I just think that people should be thinking in terms of institutional changes rather than arguing, just sort of operating in the realm of ideas.
I think that, yeah, and so they, but I think, you know, I think I probably would support, you know, some limits on lobbying for people who worked in the government for, like in the Pentagon. Should we do that for all of politics? Because there's not really, I don't think I have a principled answer here.
I think that the foreign policy, basically the establishment, has had negative influence on American politics and sort of on domestic politics. I think the influence of money on politics has been sort of mixed.
The idea of campaign finance reform, for example, is you get money out of politics. But if you get money out of politics, who gets the press coverage? Well, it's basically the governments and the party.
So it's some other small group of people determining sort of the lay of the land and what the parameters of the debate are. I think that one thing we should do is, I mean, I'm less hesitant or less conflicted about endorsing sort of a cultural change.
So for example, in areas like, for example, when you're interviewing a formal general in a newspaper or on TV, you don't just say this is a formal general. You say this guy is also on the board of this corporation or that corporation.
I mean, that, I think, changes the entire focus of the conversation.
And that was, yeah, the Washington Post wrote a story about this, how basically this is the norm.
And I was interviewed for that story.
I think there's no good reason not to do that.
I think part of what my book does is not just sort of institutional or legal things.
It's also just telling people, think about this in a different way and having sort of this cultural change, which I think takes away a lot of the credibility of the people influencing foreign policy.
Gotcha.
Okay, so let's talk about experts now. So in your article in Teluk and Taliban, you point out many ways in which we have established fields.
and if you look at the track record of societal trends associated with those
fields you know the things like suicides when you talk about psychology or crime
when you talk about criminology, or obviously, you know, Iraq and Afghanistan, when you talk about international relations, you know, things have been getting worse. But if that's the standard you're going to apply is how do the societal trends associated with the field do, then you must think that, you know, global poverty research and development economics must be amazing, right? Because we've seen like a billion people lifted out of poverty or more since 1990.
So if you're applying the same standard, then wouldn't it imply that some fields have been doing extraordinarily well? Well, yeah, actually, I do think that. I think that the reduction in poverty has come from China first and then India.
And if you ask economists, are Chinese and Indian policies better or worse than they were in the 1960s and 1970s, you could say they're definitely moving in the direction of sort of the consensus of economics. So I actually do think economics is a little bit more of a serious science than other fields.
And so, yeah, I would agree with that, actually. I think economics looks good in the context of the decline of poverty over time.
So then would you credit the fact that there hasn't been a nuclear war? Is that something you put in the pro column for international relations? Yeah, that one I think is different because poverty is something we can look at and we can say it's always existed and now it's, you know, it's getting better.
And so for nuclear weapons, it's not like we had an era of like a lot of nuclear wars and now we don't, right? We had nuclear weapons, they were invented, and that's consistent with a story where just these weapons were too horrible for anybody to use. But I think if you're going to have like a, you know, a steel man argument of, say, the case case for american empire it would be something along the lines of you know i don't believe that you know american hegemony has kept there is what basically has given us uh uh you know relative peace since 1945 but i think it would be a side a kind of like a burkean argument that you know the international system is very complex and it's working out well and just don't change anything you know too radical because potentially you know there's just so much we don't know about what the consequences of that would be well how would you respond to that by the way um i would say that you know i would say that yeah you have to take different parts of american foreign policy and i would be more sort of uh open to get rid of you know doing away with certain of them than others so first up for example regime change wars that'sed.
I think those are the low hanging fruit. I don't think you can make the case that these are, you know, these have terrible effects on the world, and I don't think you can make the case that they contribute to global order or anything like that.
Overthrowing governments is a huge source of international disorder. And then, as far as whether the US, U., whether the, you know, U.S., you know, the sort of U.S.
hegemony has been keeping peace with that, then you would move on to, say, the commitments to NATO and, you know, the presence in Japan and South Korea, and you would say, okay, you know, we've kept the peace in a relative way there. I mean, it's, you know, I think you have to sort of look, I think that there's a good reason to think that it's not necessarily the influence of the U.S.
that's behind the decline of violence. Because you look at areas, even in countries where it's like, they don't have, you know, you look at dyads where they don't have any relationship with the U.S.
on either side. Just war is just down basically across the board everywhere.
And you could say, well, that's all the American system, but I think it's hard to figure out exactly how, you know, the U.S. having a presence in East Asia or Eastern Europe, you know, that makes Africans stop fighting each other, right? And so the fact that everyone basically is not doing war anymore just gives you sort of a, this, I think, backs up John Mueller, what John Mueller thinks or what Steven Pinker thinks.
That's basically, you know, we're in the realm of ideas and people just think war is stupid. And from that perspective, you know, the U.S.
is sort of an outlier in how much it uses war. And then the U.S.
is potentially a source of instability. I think I would lean towards that view.
But I acknowledge that sort of the Burkean view of, you know, things have been working out relatively well. Let's not mess with it.
I mean, another thing that hasn't been working out well, actually, the number of being killed in, like, civil wars and civil conflicts has not gone down the way international war has. And if you look at who's behind a lot of the civil wars that have the huge death rates, I mean, that's the United States.
So not everything is actually working out well. I think keeping order within countries, you mentioned Latin America, a lot of these things are classified as high crime rates.
They could theoretically be classified as civil wars. And if you think American foreign policy is having a negative effect in Latin America, I mean, that's another contributor to the violence abroad.
So yeah, I think that's the response to it. But again, I acknowledge there potentially could be something to that argument.
So I think one of the other things to see when Pinker thinks is behind the decline of violence is also international alliances like NATO. Now, to have as a point against that, which is that while in the short term it makes us more safe, in the long term, you're like if Russia invades some North Macedonia or something, then we ought to go to war, and then this starts World War III.
So do you buy Pinker's argument
that actually these American alliances
have created a safer world?
So I haven't, I read Pinker, you know,
when it came out,
Better Angels of Our Nature about a decade ago.
I don't remember him having that argument about NATO.
I don't recall, but I'll take your word for it.
I could be wrong.
I thought it was Enlightenment Now, but yeah.
Okay, so yeah, I also read Enlightenment Now.
I don't remember.
Thank you. I don't recall, but I'll take your word for it.
I could be wrong. I thought it was Enlightenment Now, but yeah.
Okay. So yeah, I also read Enlightenment Now.
I don't remember. You know, it could be there or not.
It's a possible argument, even if it's not Pinker's. Yeah, even if it's not Pinker's argument.
Let's just take the argument. Yeah, so NATO, I mean, the argument for NATO making the world safer.
Okay, first of all, I mean, during, you know, the justification, of all, I think the justifications for NATO, right, originally there was potentially a Soviet land invasion of Europe, right? And the Soviet Union is gone, right? And so the question is, is there a potential for, all we're talking about is Russia, I don't know, what else would we would we be talking about, right? Like, that North Africa is going to invade Europe or something. It's, you know, the only potentially thing I think we're talking about here is Russia.
And, you know, it seems not to. I mean, it seems there doesn't seem to be sort of a, you know, there's a capability and there's a question of will, right? Russia is just not, you know, economically positioned to try to take on Germany or France or Western Europe.
It cares a lot about Ukraine and it cares a lot about Georgia. And I think it's pretty clear that the instability is due to Russian fears over the expansion of NATO.
So in Georgia, basically, the government launched a war to try to take back some regions that were sort of breakaway regions with alliances towards Russia. And the idea was basically they thought the United States had their back and they were trying to settle this issue to get it to NATO.
There was a great Adam Tooze substack on this about the history of Russia and NATO. So it's clear that there's been sort of a destabilizing influence.
Russia's fear that these places would become part of NATO, I think, has driven a lot of this sort of behavior abroad. I think ultimately, though, I think what it's really about actually at its root is where the antagonism comes from.
I think that the U.S. sees Russia as a potential for regime change.
I think it considers the current government illegitimate, and I think Russia doesn't, it probably doesn't think that like the U.S. is going to go into Ukraine and add them to NATO and Georgia, and then like launch an invasion of Russia, you know, that seems very unlikely.
I think that the idea is basically there's an ideological war against the idea of the legitimacy of the Russian state as a non-democracy that has a different form of government, different ideological ideas about, you know, just different things than the U.S. does.
And I think they're reacting to that. So I think this idea of sort of this idea of regime change is sort of beneath the surface and deriving a lot of tensions.
Interesting. All right, going back to the topic of expertise, you criticize the focus on peer review and specialized knowledge.
It seems that some fields, that seems like a valid criticism, right? It seems like there isn't that much specialized knowledge there to begin with, but it feels like particle physics or computational complexity. It seems like academic bureaucracy and incentives have worked and expect the people at the top of that field to be the best in the world out of that, right? But it seems like the same kind of academic institution as a field like international relations, right? So why are the two different? So I think, I do say in my experts piece, I think I say this, that it's basically, you know, I'm focusing on the social sciences, because that's what I know best.
But you said economics works well, right? Yeah, and economics works relatively well. I think, yeah, we could talk about why, but that's an interesting question too.
But, you know, I think, so Nassim Nicholas-Taleb would say that actually the peer review process doesn't work that well. He has some data on, like, where the big innovations in science comes from.
And he tends to think it comes more from the private sector. So I don't know if that's right or wrong.
It's something, you know, if you look at something like it's complicated, something like the mRNA vaccine, you know, they couldn't get the publications. It was based on the top peer reviewed journals.
And then it took, you know, Pfizer and Moderna. You know, it seems like there was a, you there's a it seems complicated because it was didn't belong on some university research in some ways and government funding I think you go to one of the big differences between the social sciences and the hard side there's a few differences the first one is there is there is some connection to reality right you can you can design the mRNA vaccine you could take it out of you know you can go even if by the peer review paper, you can take it to a pharmaceutical company.
They have an incentive to find out whether you're right. It can go out there in the real world.
It can work. And then that changes sort of the ideas in economics.
In social science, a few things, it's more complex. So sometimes in some ways it's harder to know what actually works and what doesn't.
We don't do randomized experiments on big things. We do polling questions, but not on, like, you know, this state have this economic reform and this state have this other economic reform.
We don't do anything like that. And I think part of the reason we don't do that, and this is the second big reason why social science is so hard, is because there's not as much social desirability bias.
People don't have, you know, deep-seated beliefs about the best way to get a vaccine. I guess some people do.
They say that mRNA vaccine is scary, but in general, about these physical things, right, people don't have strong beliefs about the way they want the world to work, right? And when it comes to the social sciences, people have very, very strong ideas about the way the world should work. And when you combine that with a lack of accountability, with a lack of any real-world test in the form of markets or some kind of real experimentation, people can just believe whatever they want or believe some kind of vested interest like the State Department and the Pentagon bureaucracy basically whoever's in power wants to believe and so this is why social science is hard and this is why social desirability bias is I think the enemy in the search for truth.
Now one thing about economics is I think it's It's more of a male-dominated field. It's a more, you know, if they have a mathematical sort of requirements that are more stringent, I think that weeds out a lot of people.
I think it's more of a sort of a, I think, you know, there's a sort of, you know, there's complaints from other disciplines that economics is a little bit mean and aggressive. When I was in, I got my PhD in political science, I was, to find that sometimes somebody's theory would just fall apart and then other people would not just say, okay, this is wrong, go study something else.
They would be like, oh, it's okay, just adjust it this way. And then nobody would, I always felt like people were treating others with sort of kid gloves, right? I think there was a culture in other fields, and this is political science and probably much worse in other fields, of not sort of this sort of willingness to really hurt feelings and just willingness to be wronged.
I think economics has done that better than other fields. And I think there's a movement to make, I've been talking to other people in economics who agree with this, there's been a movement to make economics like other fields, and that would potentially be disastrous.
Right, right. But now, it doesn't seem clear to me that even before calls for diversity dumbed down academia, that things were that much better.
There were fads like communism or disarmament that were popular in academia. And if you look at the Vietnam War, it was waged by people who had, you know, like Kissinger or McNamara, people who had degrees from prestigious universities.
And, you know, they were white and male, but they were still, you know, they still were disconnected from the outside world. So have, like, newer developments in academia actually made it worse? Well, no, I mean, white males can have, you know, the same pathologies as any other group.
Yeah, I think the international, the dumbing down of academia, I think, is a problem. You know, Werth Kissinger and these guys, if you look at the Vietnam War, it's actually very interesting because everyone sort of knew from like you know from the Johnson administration the Nixon administration that basically you know they were you know that it wasn't winnable that what they were saying to the public wasn't true and I think that you know that if you look at like the historical record of what politicians were saying personally they were amazingly explicit in their willingness to admit to themselves and those around them that they were doing stuff for political reasons.
So I think they were responding to basically political pressure and basically public opinion and sometimes using public opinion for their own ends. I don't think if you took professors in international relations and whatever that equivalent of that would have been and whether they supported uh vietnam um i i don't think so i think the big the big names like the ones who were not connected to the government right so kissinger i mean it's hard because he's like you know he's a guy who's in academia but also like in and out of government right and you know like it's it's it's you wouldn't expect that person to have like you know you wouldn't you wouldn't you because if he had different views basically, he wouldn't be in government.
That's the issue. His views, he had to be selected to at least be tolerable to whoever, you know, the president happened to be at the moment.
And so, yeah, I mean, I think the dumbing down of academia, I think the move away from sort of explicit, sort of more hard standards, like just basically being able to meet some standard of mathematical ability. You know, the rise of, you know, cancel culture against free speech, all these things are harmful.
It doesn't mean that there weren't a lot of pathologies before. Yeah, we can see that definitely.
Yeah, you know, whether expertise has gotten better overall. I mean, I think that, you know, so if you look at a political scientist from the 19, you know, look at just some other fields from the 1960s or 1970s, and you look at political science today, if you go to Twitter, and, you know, there's like a subject of political science.
So it's like a good gauge of like what the most prominent political scientists are saying.
And it's all stupid like graphs, like democracy has gone down 16.2% since Republicans took power in this state. It's really, really stupid.
I mean, you get the median political science from the 1960s and 1970s, there's nothing that ridiculous. So I do think it probably has gotten worse.
But, okay, so we would, the problems you're pointing out with academia seem like they're inherent to any institution that is disconnected from the market and also to something that can be empirically measured. But we would like to have expert knowledge in fields like international relations or criminology or psychology, right? So is there any way to start up institutions that can study these sort of ambiguous topics in a way that actually adds insight to the way we legislate?
You know, do we need expertise?
Do we even need expertise in international relations or criminology or psychology?
You know, I tend to believe that the costs are more, I tend to believe the costs are, you know,
they outweigh the benefits actually here.
I think if you rely on common sense for controlling crime and some basic statistics, right, I think you're better than the field of criminology. I would definitely test, you know, I would definitely, you know, take the idea.
I think there's an idea in, like, the public that, you know, if you want to stop crime and, you know, come down very hard on crime, and I think that's, you know, maybe more controversial among criminologists. But I think the problem is, actually, I wouldn't say that.
I haven't done any survey of criminologists. This is part of the problem in that you have this field called criminology.
And even if it like arrives at something that's like, you know, that's true or logical, you know, or they have like some unambiguous finding, the people, there will always be criminologists who politicians who want to do something else will rely on and they will go and they will, you know or they have like some unambiguous finding the people there will always be criminologists who politicians who want to do something else will rely on and they will go and they will you know find those people so having this category called criminologists and unless we're going to like survey the field and just do you know who knows if that will work but unless you're going to like survey the field and then just do whatever they get us in the field you're going to end up the media politicians they're going to be selecting um the people that they want during the COVID stuff. You know, they always say experts say this, experts say that.
But you look at the, you know, the something like the Great Barrington Declaration, and I just heard him around media, I thought these people were crooks and nobodies. And then I want to look at their credentials, they're like Harvard Medical School, Stanford Medical School.
And somehow when the media sites expertise, it's never these people, right? It's always the most hysterical person possible, for some kind of restriction so I think the idea you know expertise you know potentially can be valuable but the idea of expertise can be harmful and that basically you know gives gives certain people power who want to do things you know more sort of legitimacy to do things that are irrational now I think that like you know at a broader level you know I trust I trust you know things like prediction markets like economic markets things that are irrational. And I think that, like, you know, at a broader level, you know, I trust, I trust, you know, things like prediction markets, like economic markets, things that are, that don't rely on credentials, but rely on track records of getting things right.
And I would, you know, agree with Robin Hanson and others who, who would, you know, cheer for these things to have, potentially have more of an effect on policymaking or the way we think about issues. And now let's talk about politics.
So you say that one of the reasons that liberals has been winning is because liberals just care more about politics. But how does that explain why things have shifted more liberal over the last few decades? Is it just that conservatives have started caring less about politics, liberals have started caring more about politics? What's changed? Actually to a certain extent yes.
So in 2016 there was a huge mobilization effect on the left. So I do have a substat called 2016, the turning point.
I just used 2016 for convenience. But basically, if you look at like 2010 versus like 2016 to 2020, and like your probability, for example, of having attended a protest or signed a petition if you were a conservative versus liberal.
It was maybe you were two or three times more likely as a liberal in 2010, by 2016 to 2020. I mean, it was multiples of that.
It was something like 10 times more likely to have done these things. So I think that national politics and sort of the mood has a lot to do with it.
I think Trump mobilized a lot of people on the left. He did not, he mobilized a lot of voters on the right the right, like low-profile city voters who like wouldn't otherwise vote came out and voted for Trump.
And it was, it was pretty good for Republicans and they were concentrated in certain states. And that tended to be good for Republicans politically, or at least, you know, mixed bag.
While I think Trump did a terrible job of sort of motivating people who are, you know, activists or sort of people who would be bureaucrats or lawyers or, or lawyers or the people who actually make policy on a day-to-day basis. You know, he really turned those people off and made them, if anything, made them more liberal.
And so, yeah, I would say that changing engagement over time is part of the story. So I'm wondering how this theory explains why certain institutions are especially more liberal.
Take for example big tech right or compared to like a company like Walmart right. Now I don't expect that if I you know went to Walmart headquarters I'd see a whole bunch of like BLM posters but if I go to like Facebook and Facebook office I bet I'll see a few things like that or diversity is their strength or something like that.
So you know but both of these companies have faced faced pressure from liberal employees, both of these companies have to face civil rights lawsuits. It's not like in the fame companies, you have a bunch of people who have given up high salaries in order to have a position of cultural influence because they're making a lot of money there, right? So it's not like journalism or something.
So what explains why big tech especially especially is super woke yeah so big tech is such an interesting case because until 2015 and 2016 there was calls there was a lot of calls for censorship and from the media and Twitter basically didn't censor anybody until 2015 and Facebook too so basically the you know the big tech was a lot less woke than the media wanted them to be. I think that there was basically a lot of political pressure that came down on them from the top.
I think Mark Zuckerberg is, you know, Jack Dorsey are relatively not woke people compared to a lot of elites in America. When tech, you know, and I think other people have made this point, basically the initial generation of leaders in tech, they were the people who were sort of the pioneers, they were non-conformists, right? They tended to be less, they tended to do their own thing just sort of, and they would have their own political and social views, right? And then when tech sort of became established, it started to, you know, it started to draw people who are more conformist.
And that's why, you know, people have put forth the argument
that basically crypto now is more right-wing than tech
because crypto is sort of the next, you know, cutting-edge thing
that nonconformists are doing.
So I think tech, I mean, it started out, I think,
with more of a libertarian ethos,
and it sort of became the establishment, it became sort sort of thing for high conformist people to do. And, you know, I think that that's probably explains its vocification over time.
And then something like, you know, Walmart, I mean, you know, I think, you know, just sort of the ether right now is if you're an idealistic person, it's easier to be idealistic on the left than the right. I don't think the right has done a good job of providing sort of an idealistic vision that appeals to a lot of people.
When I think if you go work for Walmart, you know, your views are more maybe, you know, you get enough meaning from, you know, just getting logistics right to getting people the goods and services they need. So I think that attracts a completely different kind of person.
Sorry, I don't think I understood the difference between Walmart and Big Tech in that case. But in Big Tech, you're also doing stuff like, you know, shipping a product that like, you can get meaning out of that as well, right? Yeah.
And then in both those cases, they're like, getting older, in Big Tech they're becoming older institutions that attract informists. So why is Big Tech more woke? Yeah, so Amazon, you're working on like, logistics, right? I mean, Facebook and Google and Twitter are sort of more in the, you know, because they're not actually producing anything, I think, you know, you could say that they have to tell themselves a story about why they're doing something good for the world.
And some people, you know, believe in that story. You know, they convince themselves of it or they believe in it or they don't.
So like this kind of like, you know, like the Google thing, like don't be evil, right? I mean, this is sort of idea that they were doing something social and revolutionary, I think, was part of the ethos from the start. While Walmart, you know, they want to get you lower prices and, you know, make your life better.
But I don't think it ever had that idea that you were going to fundamentally revolutionize society by having more Walmarts, right? All right. Yeah, it's kind of analogous to American foreign policy in a way that like, you know, like Google or something like America, that they have an explicit creed and then they had to do stuff to further that creed that actually might make things worse.
That's interesting. So you write that one thing that your theory can somewhat help vindicate is authoritarian populism.
Not that you necessarily support it, but just the idea that you can have a right-wing government that pushes back on the liberal elite who just care more than conservatives, even if they're not more numerous. I wonder if compared to this, you think this theory also vindicates libertarianism more, because in that case, first of all, you don't have the funds for this rent-seeking elite to be able to survive.
So, you know, there's less journalism, academia, and also there's like less these elites can do to like actually coerce people without the help of government. Yeah.
So you're getting at sort of my, you know, the sort of the motivation behind a lot of my writing on American politics, which I, you know, I'm disturbed by wokeness. And I think that the fight against wokeness has been confused and not very effective, which is almost like that has to be self-evident because wokeness has gone so far and won so much.
And so I'm thinking about the different ways you can go about sort of working against it. So I'm not saying I'm not coming down on...
I think that to just have one sort of thing, it's either libertarianism or it's populist or authoritarian.
I think that the words like those are very sort of selectively used.
But whether it's like a more interventionist or non-interventionist, I don't think that the ideal response would be a pure version of either of these.
So what you could say for the libertarian perspective is that, and Robbie Swalve agrees in, that's the lesson he took from my article, was basically like, you know, whatever you try to pass, you say the government has to be like this or it has to be like that, it's going to get around it. And one thing they can't get around is you cut off their funding.
You stop giving money to the universities, they're not going to go out, they just don't have the funding anymore to do the stuff that they want to do. You pass a law saying they have to be politically fair and give conservatives a fair hearing.
Well, I mean, who do you think is going to be interpreting that law and deciding what a fair hearing is and what political discrimination is and all that. So yeah, there's something to that.
I mean, shrinking, like saying, you know, the government and sort of these institutions that are under the influence of, you know, bureaucrats and activists, just shrinking their role in society rather than remaking them, remaking those institutions. I mean, there's something to be set up for that.
But then, like, you know, it depends on, like, what you want, right? if you are really bothered by, you know, if you're really bothered by the direction of the culture,
and, you know, and the fact that, you know, it depends on, like, what you want, right? If you are really bothered by, you know, if you're really bothered by the direction of the culture, and, you know, and the fact that, you know, activists, you know, are, you know, propagandizing, or people who basically are, you know, just the market, I mean, whoever's, or whoever, you know, the media institutions and, you know, popular music and culture. If you're upset that they're, you know, they're selling sexual promiscuity to children, for example, you might have a more forceful response to that.
I mean, there's probably not an answer within the confines of libertarianism. It's very hard.
I mean, you could set up your own private community and go off and do something all right you know potentially there's something there but you know you could potentially say you know i don't like what's considered art now i don't like what's considered pop culture and you might just say well that's the that's the only potential thing you can do uh because i i'm not sure i follow like if you're a parent right like just don't buy your kid porn i guess you had to buy them a smartphone at some point but you have to buy them a smartphone I mean they have friends if all their if you can you know you can only afford to send them to a public school and everyone else is watching porn in the bathroom I mean I don't know like you know the people are influenced by that right it's not you know I don't think it's as easy as turn off the TV I think we all exist within this culture and you know there's a you know what other people do does affect you right right but I guess I'm skeptical'm skeptical of the extent of what right-wing government can actually influence the culture and that brings me to the next topic I want to talk to you about which is fertility right so you're more optimistic about what countries like China and Hungary can do about fertility but it seems to me that if like giving people checks doesn't get them to fuck like I don't know I don't know if like you know banning makeups on guys is going to actually make a difference well i mean so you look at you step back and you look at sort of what correlates with high fertility levels right and it seems more clearly to be associated with culture than economic situation as humans have become more able to afford kids they've tended to have less of them right so this is a pretty strong argument against it being an economic issue or largely an economic issue as a driver of differential fertility rates. And then, you know, you look at things like, so religiosity are, you know, very important.
And the question is, can government influence culture, right? I see no reason to think it can't. I think one thing, civil rights law, I think one of my main arguments on civil rights law is it actually did influence the culture.
And even that wasn't that heavy-handed compared to, say, what the Chinese government could do, potentially. So, yeah, you take the idea that fertility is a cultural issue and that government can't have an influence on culture, then it basically follows that government if it wanted to change the fertility rate or potentially a lot of other things, you know, it can do so through the control of the culture.
Right, right. But I guess one reason to be optimistic is, depending on your perspective, to be optimistic about China's fertility is, you know, like, listen, look at what they did with COVID where they were able to, like, just bolt people down in their houses until, like, there were zero cases in the area.
And if they, you know with the western countries couldn't do that so they couldn't get the code under control so what if they did something similar on fertility but there doesn't seem to be some obvious uh analogous human rights violation that you do to like um increase fertility that um that the west is not willing to try right it's just like what are you going to do that's analogous to sure sure there is you can you know ban all anti antinatalized propaganda. You can make that education system just be nothing but, you know, about how you should have children to, you know, for the fatherland.
You could, you know, tax single people and unmarried people at 100% and, you know, give all their money to 100%. So, you know, there's tons of stuff you could do.
You know, whether that's good, you know, whether it's something like zero COVID is worth, you know, the fact that China did it is pretty impressive. Whether it was worth it, you know, I think, you know, they probably got an overboard at this point.
Right. So you can debate whether it's worth it.
But I think, you know, yeah, having a competent and authoritarian government sort of opens up different possibilities. By the way, so you think by what year is China's fertility going to be 1.9, 2031? Yes, I give it 2031.
I mean, I'm the, you know, I'm the only, you know, I talk to other smart people and I'm sort of out on the limb here and, you know, the other one, you know, other smart people, they either think it's impossible or they think the will is not going to be there on the part of the Chinese government. But yeah, I take a different view and I explain it in my sub stack.
By the way, I'd make you a small bet on that if you're willing. So like I'd give you like even three to one odds in your favor.
That would be 1.9? Yeah, yeah. Okay.
Less than 1.9. Okay, but 1.9 is my median so if yeah, I'd have to take that.
Alright, yeah, yeah. We'll figure out the conditions later on.
But oh and then are you afraid that what these countries will do to actually increase fertility if that'll have a dysgenic effect, right? So if it's just that, if it's cash transfers or it's just sort of economic incentive, you know, maybe it's the people on the margins who like desperately needed the cash for going to have more babies and these are exactly the kind of people who, or, yeah, you know what I'm saying. Yeah, that's an interesting question.
I think that, you know, so if you, let's say the government went down the cultural path and just tried to propagandize people at the highest level to have as many kids as possible. Right.
are smart people or stupid people more prone to propaganda?
I think the argument could be made that smart people are.
I mean, you look at wokeness.
I mean, smart people tend to accept it a lot more than stupid people.
So maybe it's the opposite.
Maybe the smartest people will take the it a lot more than stupid people. So maybe it's the opposite.
Maybe the smartest people will take the hint most clearly and change their behavior while the stupid people won't. Or maybe the stupider are just sort of more...
It might be different kinds of propaganda appeal to different kinds of people. So something like this nationalistic might appeal disproportionately to stupid people.
or something like you know it's more idealistic and sort of divorced from reality might appeal to smart people but I don't think you know so that's one potential you know one potential issue but I historically if you look at like the way nationalism came about it was the elites generally who who were nationalistic first and then it sort of trickled down to the masses So I don don't think there's necessarily a sort of a rule of human nature that anything sort of nationalist or right-wing propaganda necessarily only disproportionately appeals to the less intelligent. But it's a fascinating question, like what the compositional effects are.
I wouldn't hazard to predict that. I think they'd give the birth rate on whether it'll be smart people or not smart people.
I don't know. Right.
It's probably still net good in either case. But I don't know about China, but for example, if the government tried to actually change the culture in America to make it more pro-natalist, I could very well imagine that it would have a counterproductive effect because then it would become countercultural or contrarian to oppose a right-wing government and not have the right on like what, you know, what kind of, so if like, yeah, if the Republican party took power and said, oh, you know, our biggest thing is getting the fertility rate up and it was like somebody like Trump who just triggered all educated people, yeah, that could probably, that would probably backfire.
You know, so in some place like China, I mean, I've seen some data that indicates that the elites are more educated or more nationalistic.
So they could actually just, you know, they could be united in favor of, you know, they could be very potentially receptive to such a message. It's so complicated because like it's like China, I think Chinese elites see themselves as part of a country that's competing with the U.S.
while U.S. elites don't see themselves really as people competing with China,
they see themselves as people competing with other Americans or competing with nature and trying to change the world or social peace. So there's completely different dynamics there, and this might be one reason why the West has become left-wing as it's become more dominant and that elites don't have anybody to compete with or try to defeat or feel superior to.
The Western gap between the recent decades of the World War II between the Westerners and the rest of the world was so large that they weren't really seen as competition. And that might change with the rise of China, but I don't think it's I don't think it's like really registered as something that's fundamentally shaping people's outlook so yeah it's yeah it's the you know the composition yeah the compositional you know effects and sort of who's responsive to propaganda these are these are fascinating questions I you know I think it's hard to predict in advance you just you know you just have to sort of you just you know you watch what people do with them you know one thing the actually you brought up the economic point so like there's a you know there's if you make like say a crap cash transfer for each child right like ten thousand dollars for example that matters a lot more to a poor person than a rich person now if you do something like you cut how much they're paying in taxes right? And I think they did this in Quebec and I think the Hungarian sort of system works like this too where if you're getting tax breaks, the rich people pay more taxes.
It could potentially be worth more to rich people to have more kids. So it's, yeah, so the structure of how it's set up would also matter quite a bit.
And, okay, final question. What should libertarians do in order to win? So, like, in the next 20, 30 years, given your theory of politics, what should the libertarians try to be? They should hope for ridiculous polarization.
They should hope for Americans to hate each other because libertarian ideas are unpopular. The only way you get them is you basically, you make them, you take over the Republican Party, and then they just win 50%
of the time no matter what they do. And they're going to have to control certain states no matter
what, and they have a lot of more freedom to do unpopular things. I think that, I think that's,
I think polarization is actually good for libertarianism, and I think we might, you know,
we might actually, they might have a good few decades, actually. Right, that also, by the way,
explains very well why wokeness has been winning in the last few decades, right? Because
Thank you. polarization is actually good for libertarianism.
And I think we might actually, they might have a good few decades, actually. Right.
That also, by the way, explains very well why wokeness has been winning in the last few decades, right? Because increased polarization, they can get unpopular things fast. Yeah.
Well, it's a cause and it's a consequence of polarization, right? So these things work together. I think what libertarians should do, and I think I'm doing a part of this, is they should really make clear to me.
So there's this idea on the populist right that we tried libertarianism,
and now wokeness has taken over.
And I'm like, okay, when did Republicans repeal the Civil Rights Act?
When did that happen?
When did they defund public education?
No, you actually haven't done anything
close to libertarianism.
And now you're making libertarianism
the scapegoat for all these negative trends.
So in my argument, in my article
about constitutions is just civil rights law, I try to make people clear that conservatives haven't been libertarian enough. They haven't even talked about this stuff or understood the downstream effects of broad interpretation of civil rights law on business and the wider culture.
So I think people should have, they should try, because people really are motivated by anti-wokeness. Some people are motivated by the idea of small government and what it can do,
but you can reach people who are motivated by anti-wokeness, and that's a lot, a lot of people on the right.
And if you explain to them how libertarianism can help them and what they want to do anyway, I think that's a good strategy.
Okay. All right.
Well, those are all the questions I had.
Richard, thanks so much for being on the podcast.
Pleasure.
Yeah, it was fun. Yeah.
Great.